From Casetext: Smarter Legal Research

In re Google Play Store Antitrust Litig.

United States District Court, Northern District of California
Aug 28, 2023
MDL 21-md-02981-JD (N.D. Cal. Aug. 28, 2023)

Opinion

MDL 21-md-02981-JD

08-28-2023

IN RE GOOGLE PLAY STORE ANTITRUST LITIGATION


ORDER RE MERITS OPINIONS OF DR. HAL J. SINGER

JAMES DONATO UNITED STATES DISTRICT JUDGE

In this multidistrict antitrust litigation, several plaintiff groups have challenged Google's Play Store practices. The Play Store is a marketplace that offers millions of apps for devices that use the Android operating system, such as phones and tablets made by Samsung and other original equipment manufacturers. The apps in the Play Store are created and supplied by independent developers, many of whom charge users a fee to acquire the app or in-app content. A central theme in all of the constituent cases of the MDL action is that Google illegally monopolized the Android app distribution market in violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Antitrust Act, which is said to have caused overcharges to consumers and other injuries.

This order pertains primarily to the consumers case, In re Google Play Consumer Antitrust Litigation, Case No. 20-cv-05761-JD. The consumers sued Google, LLC, Google Ireland Limited, Google Commerce Limited, Google Asia Pacific Pte. Limited, and Google Payment Corp. as defendants. In keeping with the parties' practice in the MDL, defendants are referred to collectively as “Google.”

The consumer plaintiffs have proffered the opinions of Dr. Hal J. Singer, an economist at the consulting firm, Econ One, and the University of Utah, as an essential part of their case against Google. Dr. Singer previously provided opinion testimony in support of the consumers' motion to certify a class. After a concurrent expert evidentiary proceeding (known informally as a “hot tub”) in which Dr. Singer exchanged views on key topics with Google's expert, Dr. Michelle Burtis, an economist at Charles River Associates, the Court denied Google's motion to exclude Dr. Singer's opinions, and certified a consumer class. See Dkt. Nos. 302 (Class Cert. Hot Tub Tr.), 383 (Class Cert. Order). An appeal of the grant of certification is pending before the circuit court. See In re Google Play Store Antitrust Litigation, Case No. 23-15285 (9th Cir.).

Unless otherwise noted, all docket number references are to the ECF docket for the MDL, Case No. 21-md-02981-JD.

The consumer plaintiffs have also asked Dr. Singer to provide opinion testimony at trial on the merits of their antitrust claims against Google. The Court has denied Google's request to defer or stay the November 6, 2023, jury trial, see Dkt. No. 499, and so proceedings have moved forward to the consideration of motions by Google for partial summary judgment and to exclude the merits opinions of certain experts on the plaintiffs' side. See Dkt. Nos. 483, 484, 487. For the experts, Google has asked to exclude under Rule 702 of the Federal Rules of Evidence (FRE) the merits opinions of Dr. Singer, and of Dr. Marc Rysman, an economist at Boston University retained by the State plaintiffs. See Dkt. Nos. 487 (Singer), 484 (Rysman).

The Match Group plaintiffs have also filed a motion for partial summary judgment on Google's counterclaims. Dkt. No. 486.

The record is a bit fuzzy on whether the plaintiff States in State of Utah v. Google LLC, Case No. 21-cv-05227-JD, intend to rely on Dr. Singer's opinions at trial. Dr. Singer offers all of his opinions on behalf of the consumer plaintiffs, and a subset on behalf of “the Consumer Plaintiffs and Plaintiff States.” Dkt. No. 489-2 (Singer Merits Report) ¶ 1. Even so, the Court understands that the States are relying primarily on the proposed testimony of Dr. Rysman, which is independent of Dr. Singer's work. In any event, this order applies to all cases involving Dr. Singer.

As is the Court's practice for Rule 702 motions involving complex expert evidence, the Court convened on August 1, 2023, a hot tub focused on the parties' main disagreements about the admissibility of the merits opinions of Drs. Singer and Rysman. See Dkt. No. 585 (Merits Hot Tub Tr.). This time, Google presented Dr. Gregory K. Leonard as its expert economist and not Dr. Burtis, on whom Google had relied for the class certification proceedings. Dr. Leonard is an economist at the consulting firm, Charles River Associates. After the hot tub, the Court posed several questions to Dr. Singer and Dr. Leonard, Dkt. No. 570, which they answered under oath on August 14, 2023. Dkt. Nos. 578, 580.

After consideration of the now fully developed record, the merits opinions of Dr. Singer are excluded under FRE 702 and the familiar standards in Daubert v. Merrell Dow Pharmaceuticals, Inc., 509 U.S. 579 (1993). The motion to exclude Dr. Rysman's merits opinions will be addressed in a separate order.

BACKGROUND

The Court provided an in-depth background for the litigation in the class certification and expert admissibility order, see Dkt. No. 383 (Class Cert. Order), and will not replow that ground here. The parties' familiarity with the background is assumed.

I. DR. SINGER'S CLASS CERTIFICATION OPINIONS

The consumer plaintiffs initially presented Dr. Singer in the class certification proceedings to opine on a proposed method of classwide proof of antitrust impact and damages. In an expert report prepared with respect to certification, Dr. Singer identified and analyzed two proposed relevant markets for the consumers' claims: an Android App Distribution Market and an In-App Aftermarket. See Class Cert. Order at 8. For the Android App Distribution Market, Dr. Singer opined that Google's “take rate,” meaning the share of revenue Google takes from developers for each app sale, would have fallen from 30.1 percent in actual practice to 23.4 percent in a competitive but-for world. This led Dr. Singer to conclude that Play Store users had paid an average overcharge of $0.30 for each app they purchased, resulting in “aggregate damages of $18.76 million” for the proposed class. Id. at 18. For the In-App Aftermarket, which involves purchases a user makes within an app after buying it, Dr. Singer opined that Google's take rate for in-app content would have fallen from 29.2 percent in actual practice to 14.8 percent in a competitive but-for world, resulting in an “average $1.34 consumer savings per transaction and an aggregate damage figure of $4.71 billion.” Id. Dr. Singer offered an alternative damages model based on Google's Play Points rewards program, and concluded that in a competitive but-for world, the Play Points program would have “expanded to be worth an average of $0.77 per transaction, or approximately 8.7 percent of consumer spend,” resulting in aggregate damages of $2.71 billion. Id. at 22; Singer Class Cert. Report ¶ 255.

In his class certification report, Dkt. No. 254-4 (Singer Class Cert. Report), Dr. Singer offered opinions on other elements of the consumer plaintiffs' antitrust claims, e.g., that Google has engaged in anticompetitive conduct in the Android App Distribution Market and In-App Aftermarket. Google did not challenge the admissibility of those opinions. See Dkt. No. 252.

For certification purposes, the Court determined that the Rule 23 questions of commonality and predominance could be answered for the class as a whole on the basis of Dr. Singer's overcharge models for the Android App Distribution Market and In-App Aftermarket, and so deferred for another day consideration of the Play Points model. Class Cert. Order at 23. The Court overruled Google's primary objection that Dr. Singer's overcharge models were inadmissible under FRE 702 because they were based on a faulty “pass-through” formula that Dr. Singer used to quantify how much of Google's developer fees consumers would ultimately end up paying. As the Court noted, the pass-through formula was a “critical element of Dr. Singer's overcharge analysis,” and “was an input for both the Rochet-Tirole model (which Dr. Singer used for the Android App Distribution Market) and the Landes-Posner model (used for the In-App Aftermarket).” Id. at 9, 17. The pass-through formula was essential because app developers independently set the prices of the apps and in-app content they make available through the Play Store. The purpose of the pass-through formula was to quantify the “portion of the supracompetitive cost imposed on developers” by Google that was “passed through” to, or more aptly paid by, consumers. Id. at 17. This is a critical part of the consumers' claim that they overpaid for apps and in-app content as a result of Google's anticompetitive conduct, and so a classwide method of determining the pass-through rate was vital to the certification motion.

Dr. Singer used a pass-through formula “derived from a logit model,” which Dr. Singer believed would correctly model “the demand curve faced by the developers who sell apps and content in the Google Play Store.” Id. Dr. Singer opined in his certification report that “the pass- through formula may ultimately be expressed as ‘one minus the share' an app has in its selfselected Play Store category.” Id. at 17-18. To unpack this at a high level, “category” refers to Google's own denomination of broad topical groupings such as “education,” “game,” “sports,” and the like used to organize apps in the Play Store. If an app has, say, a 20% share of the sports category, then for that app, Dr. Singer would estimate a pass-through rate of 1 - 20% = 80%. Dr. Singer's ultimate calculation of the overcharges paid by consumers entails several additional steps, but this logit-based pass-through formula is an essential core element of his overall approach.

As the proponents of Dr. Singer's expert testimony, plaintiffs had the burden of establishing its admissibility over Google's objections. See Southland Sod Farms v. Stover Seed Co., 108 F.3d 1134, 1141-42 (9th Cir. 1997) (plaintiff, as “proponent of scientific evidence” had “burden of establishing that the evidence is scientifically valid,” but nevertheless concluding that “[b]ecause Defendants have not demonstrated that Plaintiffs are unable to make such a showing as a matter of law, we will not exclude [plaintiffs' expert's] testimony under Daubert.”). An important aspect of the admissibility analysis at the class certification stage was a careful consideration of the comments made by Google's proffered expert, Dr. Michelle Burtis, in her certification report and at the hot tub with Dr. Singer. The goal of the hot tub was to provide Google with the opportunity, through its expert, to illuminate its concerns about Dr. Singer's work, and to give Dr. Singer an opportunity for a real-time response. At the Court's direction, Dr. Burtis and Dr. Singer jointly prepared a list of discussion topics for the hot tub, in descending order of importance for the question of certification. See Dkt. No. 284, Ex. 1.

Critically, for certification purposes, Dr. Burtis did not say that Dr. Singer's opinions, including his pass-through analysis, were “junk science” that ought to be excluded. See Ellis v. Costco Wholesale Corp., 657 F.3d 970, 982 (9th Cir. 2011). To the contrary, and with specific respect to Dr. Singer's pass-through model, Dr. Burtis stated: “As I said, the model exists in the literature; and I'm not here to say that this is a model that nobody uses. I won't say that about this model. Whether it's the right model, I don't know, and I don't have an opinion.” Class Cert. Hot Tub Tr. at 24:12-15. Dr. Burtis also said, again in specific reference to Dr. Singer's pass-through model: “Regarding this model, I would say, I don't think this model itself is junk science. I wouldn't say that. All I'm saying here is that, you know, Dr. Singer, he didn't try to adapt the model, to really test the issue of common impact here. He didn't do anything to test.” Id. at 26:15.

Dr. Burtis's expert report was equally benign about Dr. Singer's pass-through formula as a method of analysis. See Dkt. No. 254-5 (Burtis Report). Dr. Burtis devoted three short paragraphs in a 125-page report to the question of whether a logit demand model could, as a matter of sound economics, generate reliable pass-through rates in the Play Store market. Id. at ¶¶ 306-08. She did not say that a credible economist would never use a logit model in the Play Store context. Dr. Burtis agreed that the logit model was “frequently used in economics.” Id. ¶ 306. Her main substantive criticism was that Dr. Singer was wrong to use Google's app categories for the logit analysis, and that he should have come up with his own customized groupings of apps into “more appropriate categories” that would “ensure that substitutes are properly grouped together.” Id. ¶ 311; see also id. ¶ 279 (“The ‘categories' used by Dr. Singer, which are integral to the results, are not based on any economic analysis or reasoning but are simply the categories used in Google Play.”). Dr. Burtis also faulted Dr. Singer for not accounting for variables such as developers' marginal costs and pricing strategies to set prices that end in $0.99 cents. See id. ¶¶ 303-04, 313.

Overall, Dr. Burtis did not challenge the fundamental soundness of Dr. Singer's approach in light of the economic literature, and instead offered criticisms that went to the weight of his opinions, and not to admissibility. Consequently, after conducting an independent analysis of Dr. Singer's work and weighing Google's objections, the Court determined that Dr. Singer's testimony was admissible for certification purposes. See Class Cert. Order. Google did not challenge the expert qualifications of Dr. Singer, a well-credentialed economist who is active in the antitrust field. See id. at 8. On the record as it then stood, plaintiffs met their burden of establishing admissibility, and Google and Dr. Burtis did not state objections that demonstrated that Dr. Singer's opinions warranted exclusion as junk science under Rule 702 or Daubert, 509 U.S. 579.

II. DR. SINGER'S MERITS OPINIONS

The situation has developed at the merits stage. The consumer plaintiffs proffer Dr. Singer again to provide expert testimony on the substance of their antitrust claims, over Google's objections. Google does not challenge Dr. Singer's qualifications as an expert, the relevance of his testimony, or all of his opinions. Its motion to exclude is directed only at the injury and damages portions of Dr. Singer's work, and it challenges his opinions on these topics as unreliable under FRE 702 and Daubert. See Dkt. No. 487.

In substantial measure, Dr. Singer's injury and damages opinions are the same in his class certification and merits reports. The pass-through formula is the same, and Dr. Singer again uses the Rochet-Tirole model for the Android App Distribution Market and the Landes-Posner model for the In-App Aftermarket. Singer Merits Report ¶¶ 288, 326, 358. But this time, Dr. Singer offers aggregate damages figures calculated six different ways: (1) aggregate overcharge damages of $23.83 million for the Android App Distribution Market; (2) aggregate overcharge damages of $7.00 billion for the In-App Aftermarket; (3) a “discount model” based on Google Play Points, calculated for a combined Android App Distribution Market and In-App Aftermarket “where the locus of competition is on the consumer subsidy,” producing $3.92 billion in damages; (4) a “single take rate” damages calculation, “where competition occurs only with respect to the take rate in a single, combined market,” resulting in $3.66 billion in damages; (5) an “Amazon Discount Model,” using the “Amazon Appstore's consumer discounts” as a “reasonable benchmark for calculating aggregate damages,” producing $8.039 billion in damages; and (6) a single-market “hybrid model,” in which competition occurs with respect to both the take rate and buyer-side subsidy, producing $3.81 billion in aggregate damages. Id. ¶¶ 414-21, 441-45.

With respect to the pass-through formula, Dr. Singer again states that, “when demand is logit, a developer's pass-through rate can be estimated as one minus that developer's category share.” Id. ¶ 358. The pass-through formula continues to be an essential input in his calculation of aggregate overcharge damages for the Android App Distribution Market, see id. at 141, Table 6, and the In-App Aftermarket, see id. at 155, Table 8. The pass-through rate is also an input for the “single take rate” model, see id. at 265, Table A4, and the “hybrid” model, see id. at 267, Table A5. It is not an input for the “discount” model, see id. at 191, Table 16, or the Amazon Discount model, see id. at 206, Table 21.

Google's response to Dr. Singer has changed since class certification. Most notably, Dr. Burtis has yielded the floor to a new expert witness, Dr. Leonard. See Dkt. No. 487. Dr. Leonard took a fresh look at Dr. Singer's opinions and proffered, as will be discussed, a different response from Dr. Burtis. As the Court stated at the merits hot tub, it has some misgivings about Google taking a second shot at Dr. Singer's testimony with a new witness. Even so, the path to a fair result often has some turns, particularly as the record develops in a complex antitrust dispute such as this one. Consideration of Google's revised FRE 702 presentation based on a new expert witness serves “the end of ascertaining the truth and securing a just determination” in this multidistrict litigation. Fed.R.Evid. 102.

DISCUSSION

I. LEGAL STANDARDS

As Federal Rule of Evidence 702 states, a “witness who is qualified as an expert by knowledge, skill, experience, training, or education may testify in the form of an opinion or otherwise if: (a) the expert's scientific, technical, or other specialized knowledge will help the trier of fact to understand the evidence or to determine a fact in issue; (b) the testimony is based on sufficient facts or data; (c) the testimony is the product of reliable principles and methods; and (d) the expert has reliably applied the principles and methods to the facts of the case.”

This rule is expected to be updated soon. By order of the United States Supreme Court dated April 24, 2023, a proposed amendment to FRE 702 will take effect on December 1, 2023, barring any contrary Congressional action. See https://www.supremecourt.gov/orders/ ordersofthecourt/22 (“4/24/23 Rules of Evidence”); 28 U.S.C. § 2074. The proposed amendment clarifies that an expert witness's opinion testimony is admissible under FRE 702 only “if the proponent demonstrates to the court that it is more likely than not that” the proposed testimony satisfies subsections (a) through (d) of the Rule. Subsection (d) will also be replaced in its entirety to provide that the expert's opinion must “reflect[] a reliable application of the principles and methods to the facts of the case.” See Supreme Court's 4/24/23 Order. In the Court's view, the proposed amendment is not a sea change but rather an amplification of existing FRE 702 standards. For present purposes, the Court is mindful of FRE 702 as it stands today and as it will be imminently amended.

As the Court has observed in another case, the FRE 702 admissibility standard does not change with the different stages of litigation or become more rigorous as a case progresses from class certification to the merits stage. See In re Capacitors Antitrust Litigation, MDL Case No. 17-md-02801-JD, 2020 WL 870927, at *2 (N.D. Cal. Feb. 21, 2020). At all stages, “Rule 702 of the Federal Rules of Evidence tasks a district court judge with ‘ensuring that an expert's testimony both rests on a reliable foundation and is relevant to the task at hand.'” Elosu v. Middlefork Ranch Inc., 26 F.4th 1017, 1023 (9th Cir. 2022) (quoting Daubert, 509 U.S. at 597).

Reliability is the touchstone. “The test of reliability is flexible,” and “the trial court has discretion to decide how to test an expert's reliability as well as whether the testimony is reliable, based on the particular circumstances of the particular case.” Primiano v. Cook, 598 F.3d 558, 564 (9th Cir. 2010) (cleaned up). As the amendment of FRE 702 emphasizes, the burden of establishing the reliability of the proposed expert witness testimony rests with the proponent of the expert evidence. See Southland Sod, 108 F.3d at 1141. The Court “must decide any preliminary question about whether a witness is qualified, . . ., or evidence is admissible,” and “[i]n so deciding, the court is not bound by evidence rules, except those on privilege.” Fed.R.Evid. 104(a). When “admissibility determinations . . . hinge on preliminary factual questions,” those factual matters must be “established by a preponderance of proof”; application of the “preponderance standard ensures that before admitting evidence, the court will have found it more likely than not that the technical issues and policy concerns addressed by the Federal Rules of Evidence have been afforded due consideration.” Bourjaily v. United States, 483 U.S. 171, 175 (1987).

II. THE PASS-THROUGH FORMULA

In his merits opinions, Dr. Singer used a pass-through formula “specific to logit” that was developed by the economists Nathan Miller, Marc Remer, and Gloria Sheu, and he applied that formula here “to calculate pass-through rates for each Play Store category.” Singer Merits Report ¶¶ 358, 360. The Google Play Store has approximately 33 app categories for “Beauty,” “Dating,” “Events,” “Health and Fitness,” “Productivity,” “Weather,” and similar categories, and app developers self-select a category when positioning their apps in the Play Store. Id. ¶¶ 349-50 & Table 13. In Dr. Singer's view, “Miller et. al. demonstrate mathematically that, when firms are subjected to an industrywide change in costs, the profit-maximizing change in the price of a particular product i in response to a one dollar change in a firm's marginal cost is equal to [M-Qi]/M, where M is the size of the category -- inclusive of the outside good -- and Qi is the quantity sold of product i. This means that, when demand is logit, a developer's pass-through rate can be estimated as one minus that developer's category share, consistent with what has been shown previously in the peer-reviewed economics literature.” Id. ¶ 358.

The reliability of this logit-based pass-through rate depends on whether Dr. Singer reliably “estimate[d] logit demand systems for each of the categories used by Google.” Id. ¶ 354. “In a logit demand system, each product within the system has its own (nonlinear) demand curve, given by the following formula: ln(Sj / S0) = fy + aPj.” Id. ¶ 348. Dr. Singer explains, “Sj is the share of product j, and S0 is the share of the outside good -- that is, the proportion of consumers that do not purchase any of the products at issue. The term fyj represents factors other than price that shift demand (and thus share). These are modeled as fixed effects unique to a given App and purchase type (Initial Downloads, In-App, and Subscription). The model also includes fixed effects by state, and for sub-products within a given App (e.g., Pandora Plus versus Pandora Premium).” Id. Dr. Singer states that “[e]conomists have frequently used logit to analyze a variety of economic phenomena, including (but not limited to) potentially anticompetitive conduct in markets with differentiated products.” Id. He also states that “[t]he standard logit model is widely used by economists to estimate pass-through in a range of contexts,” and he acknowledges that the logit demand system implies “that developers in a given category pass through cost savings according to their dominance (or lack thereof) in the category, as measured by their market share within that category.” Id. ¶¶ 351, 356.

In response to these and related propositions by Dr. Singer, Dr. Leonard presented several new critiques and points of information. The most salient of these concerned the logit model's “IIA” property. As Dr. Leonard stated in his report, the logit model “exhibits what is called the ‘independence of irrelevant alternatives' (IIA) property. The IIA property places strong restrictions on substitution patterns between products (i.e., the own- and cross-price elasticities of demand). Because of IIA's restrictiveness regarding substitution patterns, from the early 1980s, the economics literature has warned about the use of the logit model of demand.” Dkt. No. 489-3 (Leonard Report) at 60 n.76; see also id. ¶ 153. This was new information in that Dr. Burtis had not specifically identified or highlighted the IIA property in a meaningful way. She did not use that term in her report. See Dkt. No. 254-5. She and Dr. Singer did not identify the IIA restriction as a topic for debate at the certification hot tub. See Dkt. No. 284, Ex. 1. During the hot tub discussion, Dr. Burtis never expressly mentioned IIA and made only a passing mention of substitution late in the proceeding. See Dkt. No. 302 at 88:22-91:7.

In significant contrast, Dr. Leonard put the IIA property of logit front and center in his challenge to Dr. Singer's analysis. Dr. Singer does not seriously dispute Dr. Leonard's observations about the IIA property itself. In the experts' joint statement of topics for the merits hot tub, Dr. Singer said that he “will address Google's claim that he misapplied logit because the property of ‘IIA' or ‘proportional substitution' -- when prices for one product increase, consumers switch to substitutes in proportion to their relative shares -- is allegedly not satisfied.” Dkt. No. 540-2 at 12. Dr. Singer added that he “will explain that it is reasonable to conclude that the proportional substitution property is satisfied here, as evidenced by his regressions .... Moreover, logit is routinely and reliably used as an approximation even when IIA is not strictly satisfied ....” Id. Dr. Leonard, on his part, stated that “[o]ne feature of the logit model Dr. Singer used is the ‘irrelevance of independent alternatives' property, or IIA, which holds that all goods in the market where demand is being studied are substitutes for one another in proportion to their share of that market. There is an economic consensus that if real world demands do not satisfy this property, then the model will yield unreliable results....As applied to demand for Android apps, the IIA principle means that all apps in a given app category must be substitutes for each other, and must be substitutes in proportion to their share of that category. However, Dr. Singer concedes that apps in each category fail this condition. This makes his entire model unreliable.” Id. at 12-13.

The IIA issue was raised in the parties' Rule 702 motion briefing, see Dkt. No. 487 at 6-10, Dkt. No. 508 at 5-9, and was discussed in detail at the merits hot tub. In his opening comments about Dr. Singer's work, Dr. Leonard underscored that “the big problem with the logit model is the so-called IIA assumption.... [S]ince probably 1977 or so there have been well-known tests that test for the IIA assumption. And it's also very well known you shouldn't just assume logit because it has these very restrictive assumptions on substitution patterns . . . basically a proportional substitution.” Merits Hot Tub Tr. at 27:18-25. Dr. Singer did not take serious issue with Dr. Leonard. When the Court asked, “what is the source of the proportionate substitution or demand proposition, is that Miller?” Dr. Singer said, “Oh, I think it will be in Miller, but it will be on any -- in any -- I don't think that's disputed. It's proportional substitution. That's what the -that's what the IIA property is about.” Id. at 52:8-14.

This discussion at the hot tub, and in the merits reports generally, put a much finer point than at class certification on the question of whether Dr. Singer's logit-based pass-through formula was sufficiently valid and reliable to be admissible. The Court inquired further into the question when it called for additional comments by the economists after the hot tub proceeding. Dkt. No. 570. Among other inquiries, the Court asked: “(A) What economic literature states that a regression analysis is a reliable way of (i) testing for the IIA assumption in the logit model, or (ii) confirming that a logit model can be used to reliably measure the relevant demand curve here?” And, “(B) To what extent can IIA be ‘not strictly satisfied' before the use of logit model becomes unreliable? How can the Court know that this limit has not been crossed here? How close is the ‘approximation' that Dr. Singer posits, and how can the Court have confidence that his logit model has produced a sufficiently reliable approximation of pass-through here even if the apps in each category are not proportional substitutes for one another?” Id. at 2.

Dr. Singer and Dr. Leonard filed sworn answers to the follow-up questions. Dkt. Nos. 578, 580. Dr. Leonard stated that the “defining characteristic of the logit model is the IIA assumption, which forces a particular substitution pattern on the data, regardless of how consumers actually substitute among products in the marketplace being studied.” Dkt. No. 578 ¶ 6. Dr. Leonard also stated that, in the “specific case of Android apps, given the category definitions that Dr. Singer used, the IIA assumptions of the logit model that all apps are substitutes and substitution is proportional to shares are clearly false,” because “[s]ome of the apps within a category are not substitutes for each other at all, let alone in a manner proportional to their respective shares.” Id. ¶ 19. To illustrate, Dr. Leonard gave the example of “Rosetta Stone,” “Duolingo,” and “PictureThis - Plant Identifier,” which are “three apps in the Education category.” Id. Rosetta Stone has less than a 5% category share; Duolingo has around 15%; and PictureThis - Plant Identifier has around 20%. Id. Dr. Leonard observed that, “[w]ith entirely different functionality than the language learning apps, there can be no serious argument that PictureThis - Plant Identifier is any kind of substitute at all for Rosetta Stone,” and yet, “the logit model, with its IIA assumption, assumes that if Rosetta Stone raised its price and some customers substituted away, PictureThis - Plant Identifier would capture a larger percentage of these switching customers than Duolingo . . . simply because PictureThis - Plant Identifier has a larger category share than Duolingo.” Id. In Dr. Leonard's view, “[t]his makes no economic sense at all.” Id.

Dr. Singer stated in his response to the follow-up questions that “IIA is a property of logit,” and “[a]pplied here, IIA implies that consumers will tend to substitute among different Apps within a given category in proportion to an Apps' share in that category (‘proportional substitution' or ‘proportionate shifting').” Dkt. No. 580 ¶ 13. Dr. Singer's comments were consistent with Dr. Leonard in terms of how the IIA assumption would be expected to play out in the context of apps in the Play Store: “Suppose the price of App A increases. To avoid the price hike, some consumers will switch to different Apps within the same category. Suppose further that App B is very popular, with a category share of 50 percent, and that App C is less popular, with a category share of just one percent. Under proportional substitution, these consumers are more likely to switch to the (more popular) App B than they are to switch to the (less popular) App C. Specifically, consumers are, on average, fifty times more likely to switch to App B than App C under this assumption.” Id.

Critically, Dr. Singer did not explain why this assumption would still make economic sense if App A and App C were more similar, like Duolingo and Rosetta Stone, and App B were entirely different, such as PictureThis - Plant Identifier. As Dr. Leonard suggests, it is intuitively obvious that users looking for an app to learn Italian will not try to avoid a price hike by switching to an app that identifies the type of geranium in their kitchen. This intuition highlights a fundamental problem that a jury would face if Dr. Singer's opinions were presented at trial. It may be possible for a jury to make reasonable decisions about the substitutability of certain apps at a very high and general level, but Dr. Singer's analysis does not provide usable guidance on what to do with the myriad of differences and distinctions between apps within the Google Play Store categories. He does not provide any boundaries on substitution in broad app categories that contain many unlike products. This would create a serious risk of the jury simply guessing about proportionate substitution and ultimately the pass-through of fees to consumers.

Dr. Singer's position with respect to the IIA property of logit is further eroded by one of the main authorities he cited in his follow-up response and attached in full as an exhibit: Kenneth Train, Logit, in Discrete Choice Methods with Simulation 34 (Cambridge University Press 2009). See Dkt. No. 580, Ex. 15. Professor Train's chapter on logit deepens rather than alleviates the Court's concern that the logit model cannot be reliably used in the context of apps in the Google Play Store in the way Dr. Singer has done in his analysis. Professor Train starts with the observation that “[b]y far the easiest and most widely used discrete choice model is logit.” Id. at 34. He explains that “[i]ts popularity is due to the fact that the formula for the choice probabilities takes a closed form and is readily interpretable.” Id.

From there, he sounds many cautionary notes about the appropriateness of its use. He states, for example, that “[l]ogit models can capture taste variations, but only within limits. In particular, tastes that vary systematically with respect to observed variables can be incorporated in logit models, while tastes that vary with unobserved variables or purely randomly cannot be handled.” Id. at 43. Also, “if taste variation is at least partly random, logit is a misspecification. As an approximation, logit might be able capture the average tastes fairly well even when tastes are random, since the logit formula seems to be fairly robust to misspecifications. The researcher might therefore choose to use logit even when she knows that tastes have a random component, for the sake of simplicity. However, there is no guarantee that a logit model will approximate the average tastes. And even if it does, logit does not provide information on the distribution of tastes around the average. This distribution can be important in many situations ....” Id. at 44. Further, “[p]roportionate substitution can be realistic for some situations, in which case the logit model is appropriate. In many settings, however, other patterns of substitution can be expected, and imposing proportionate substitution through the logit model can lead to unrealistic forecasts.” Id. at 48.

These comments support Dr. Leonard's critiques and undercut the reliability of Dr. Singer's work. Dr. Singer endeavors to use the logit model in an overly simple way to represent the demand curve for developers in the Play Store. In Dr. Singer's model, when the price of an app goes up, the consumer will necessarily switch to a different app in the same category, based purely on the popularity of those other apps. As Dr. Singer acknowledges, this approach works only if the apps within each category are proportional substitutes for one another. This is an unproven assumption in Dr. Singer's work. It cannot be squared with the economic literature such as that of Professor Train, and it flies in the face of the huge diversity of apps within the Play Store categories. As Dr. Leonard has noted, given the broad categories in the Google Play Store, which developers self-select, the IIA's assumption that “all apps are substitutes and substitution is proportional to shares” is not factually supported in this context. Dkt. No. 578 ¶ 19.

Dr. Singer's main defense is to say that “IIA is reliably established here” because he has “confirmed using standard regression methods from the economic literature that the logit demand curve is well-specified here.” Dkt. No. 580 at 8. The problem is that nothing validates the use of regressions in this manner. Professor Train certainly did not identify this kind of regression analysis as a way of validating a use of logit. He did say that the “independence assumption . . . in fact can be interpreted as a natural outcome of a well-specified model,” and that “[i]n a deep sense, the ultimate goal of the researcher is to represent utility so well that the only remaining aspects constitute simply white noise; that is, the goal is to specify utility well enough that a logit model is appropriate. Seen in this way, the logit model is the ideal rather than a restriction.” Id., Ex. 15 at 35-36. But this observation does not appear to fit Dr. Singer's model. He has not specified his observed variables so well that “the remaining, unobserved portion of utility is essentially ‘white noise.'” Id. at 35. Rather, as Dr. Leonard notes, Dr. Singer's model “includes only the app price and a set of SKU-time-state indicator variables. This leaves plenty of room for substantial correlation among the remaining unobserved portions of a consumer's utilities for apps. For example, consumers who like a given single-shooter game likely also like other singleshooter games ....That is, such consumers will exhibit positive correlation among unobserved parts of their utilities for single-shooter games. The unobserved portions of their utilities are not just ‘white noise.' The price and indicator variables included in Dr. Singer's model would not capture this correlation in consumers' preferences over single-shooter games and therefore the ‘ideal' would not be met and the logit model would not apply.” Dkt. No. 578 ¶ 29.

Dr. Leonard has also pointed out that Dr. Singer did not compare the “fit” of the logit model with “that of an alternative demand model.” Id. ¶ 14. And in Dr. Leonard's view, Dr. Singer's claim that he “obtained the ‘right' signs and statistical significance on the price coefficients in his regression model as support for the logit model” is “a low bar,” because “all demand models predict lower share (i.e., lower quantity) when price increases and vice versa.” Id. at 8 n.9. Similarly, the States' expert, Dr. Rysman, was asked in his deposition whether it would be sufficient for him “to determine that a standard logit model was appropriate that there was a negative correlation between price and demand,” and he responded, “Not by itself[,] that wouldn't tell me that the logit model was appropriate.” Dkt. No. 487-4 at 68:21-69:2. While plaintiffs have pointed out that Dr. Rysman “had not read Dr. Singer's report,” Dkt. No. 508 at 7 n.5, it is hard to see why that would matter for purposes of the answer Dr. Rysman gave, which stands on its own and bolsters Dr. Leonard's critique of Dr. Singer's work.

Overall, the record at the merits stage is substantially more developed than at class certification, and establishes that Dr. Singer's pass-through model is not within accepted economic theory and literature, and is based on assumptions about the Play Store apps that are not supported by the evidence. The model does not give the jury a sound basis on which to make a reasoned and reasonable judgment about antitrust impact and damages in a product market that does not show proportional substitution across alternatives, at least not on a Play Store category share basis as Dr. Singer has modeled.

Because that pass-through model is the keystone of Dr. Singer's overcharge analysis, his opinions based on it must be excluded. The purpose of judicial gatekeeping under Rule 702 is “to make certain that an expert . . . employs in the courtroom the same level of intellectual rigor that characterizes the practice of an expert in the relevant field.” Kumho Tire Co., Ltd. v. Carmichael, 526 U.S. 137, 152 (1999). Dr. Singer's use of a logit approach to model the demand curve faced by app developers in the Play Store, ultimately producing the simple pass-through formula of one minus the app's share of its category, was a decision that “fell outside the range where experts might reasonably differ, and where the jury must decide among the conflicting views of different experts, even though the evidence is ‘shaky.'” Id. at 153 (quoting Daubert, 509 U.S. at 596). Because the characteristics of a logit model and its IIA property are enough to find that Dr. Singer's pass-through formula here is not sufficiently reliable to be admitted under Rule 702, the Court declines to reach Google's other arguments that the pass-through formula suffers from additional admissibility shortcomings. Since Dr. Singer's pass-through formula is not reliable enough to be admitted, his testimony about that formula, and his injury and damages opinions that necessarily rely on it, are excluded.

Google's motion for leave to file a supplemental brief in support of its Rule 702 motion, Dkt. No. 541, is granted. For the sake of deciding this issue on as complete a record as possible, the Court reviewed and considered Google's supplemental brief and attachments, as well as plaintiffs' opposition and attached supplemental reports. Dkt. Nos. 541-1, 550.

III. THE CONSUMER SUBSIDY MODELS

As an alternative approach, Dr. Singer offered “consumer subsidy” models that did not use the pass-through formula. Opinions with respect to these models are also excluded.

The main reason for exclusion is that the analysis behind the subsidy models is too anemic to let them go to a jury. For the Play Points model, Dr. Singer relies on wholly speculative assumptions that make his opinions ipse dixit unsuitable for admission at trial. For example, he states, with no visible factual support, that “the structure of Play Points is a reasonable facsimile of what an expanded program might look like in a competitive but-for world,” Singer Merits Report ¶ 373, and that “[c]onsumers would have enhanced economic incentives to enroll and participate in a Play Points offering more valuable incentives in the but-for world, just as consumers have more incentives to participate in a more generous credit card rewards program than a less generous one.” Id. ¶ 381. Why any of this might be true is not said. Dr. Singer's Play Points calculations also rest on the assumption that, in the but-for world, Google “maintains a 60 percent market share with an inelastic supply response from Google's rivals.” Id. ¶ 386. Dr. Singer says that “[e]ven in the presence of substantial competition, I assume conservatively that Google would have retained a substantial market share of 60 percent,” because “this was approximately AT&T's market share in the long-distance market after competitive entry.” Id. ¶ 331. It is again not explained, and is certainly not obvious, why the situation AT&T faced in the telecom market in the 1980s is a good benchmark for Google's app store practices today. As Dr. Leonard aptly commented, “[t]he economics of long distance service in the 1980s and early 1990s differed substantially from the but-for world for Android app stores in this case,” and “without an in-depth analysis,” there is an insufficient basis “to think that the entry costs, requirements, and market opportunity for one or more new firms to compete with the incumbent would be the same in the Android app store marketplace as was the case in the 1980s and early 1990s long distance service marketplace.” Dkt. No. 578 ¶¶ 43-44.

So too for Dr. Singer's other consumer subsidy model. Dr. Singer devotes a paltry four paragraphs to a purported Amazon Coins discount damages model. Singer Merits Report ¶¶ 41720. Not surprisingly, those four paragraphs do not adequately explain why or how the Amazon Appstore might be a “reasonable approximation” of damages here. Id. ¶ 418. Dr. Singer again simply asserts, with no real analysis or data, that “Amazon's aggregate discount . . . on third-party devices is a reasonable benchmark for estimating aggregate damages.” Id. ¶ 419.

“[N]othing in either Daubert or the Federal Rules of Evidence requires a district court to admit opinion evidence that is connected to existing data only by the ipse dixit of the expert. A court may conclude that there is simply too great an analytical gap between the data and the opinion proffered.” General Electric Co. v. Joiner, 522 U.S. 136, 146 (1997). That is the case here for Dr. Singer's consumer subsidy models.

CONCLUSION

Google's motion to exclude the merits opinion testimony of Dr. Singer, Dkt. No. 487, is granted.

IT IS SO ORDERED.


Summaries of

In re Google Play Store Antitrust Litig.

United States District Court, Northern District of California
Aug 28, 2023
MDL 21-md-02981-JD (N.D. Cal. Aug. 28, 2023)
Case details for

In re Google Play Store Antitrust Litig.

Case Details

Full title:IN RE GOOGLE PLAY STORE ANTITRUST LITIGATION

Court:United States District Court, Northern District of California

Date published: Aug 28, 2023

Citations

MDL 21-md-02981-JD (N.D. Cal. Aug. 28, 2023)