From Casetext: Smarter Legal Research

In re Cipro Cases I & Ii.[nine Coordinated Cases *]

Court of Appeal, Fourth District, Division 1, California.
Oct 31, 2011
200 Cal.App.4th 442 (Cal. Ct. App. 2011)

Opinion

No. D056361.

2011-10-31

In re CIPRO CASES I & II.[Nine coordinated cases *]

See Cal. Jur. 3d, Monopolies and Restraints of Trade, §§ 33, 35, 36, 45; Cal. Civil Practice (Thomson Reuters 2011) Business Litigation, § 63:22; 1 Witkin, Summary of Cal. Law (10th ed. 2005) Contracts, § 591 et seq. Lieff, Cabraser, Heimann & Bernstein, San Francisco, Joseph R. Saveri, Eric B. Fastiff, Brendan Glackin, Jordan Elias, Dean M. Harvey; Krause, Kalfayan, Benink & Slavens, San Diego, Ralph B. Kalfayan; Zwerling, Schachter & Zwerling and Dan Drachler for Plaintiffs and Appellants.Mark A. Lemley, Stanford, for 78 Law, Economics, Business and Public Policy Professors as Amici Curiae on behalf or Plaintiffs and Appellants.Edleson & Rezzo, San Diego, Joann F. Rezzo; and Kathryn E. Karcher for Defendants and Respondents.Luce, Forward, Hamilton & Scripps, San Diego, Charles A. Bird, Christopher J. Healey, Todd R. Kinnear; Jones Day, Kevin D. McDonald; Bartlit Beck Herman Palencher & Schott and Peter B. Bensinger, Jr., for Defendant and Respondent Bayer Corporation. Stinson, Morrison, Hecker, David E. Everson, Heather S. Woodson and Victoria Smith for Defendants and Respondents Hoechst Marion Roussel, Inc., The Rugby Group, Inc., and Watson Pharmaceuticals, Inc.Kirkland and Ellis, Edwin John U, Karen N. Walker, and Gregory Skidmore for Defendant and Respondent Barr Laboratories, Inc.


See Cal. Jur. 3d, Monopolies and Restraints of Trade, §§ 33, 35, 36, 45; Cal. Civil Practice (Thomson Reuters 2011) Business Litigation, § 63:22; 1 Witkin, Summary of Cal. Law (10th ed. 2005) Contracts, § 591 et seq.

Lieff, Cabraser, Heimann & Bernstein, San Francisco, Joseph R. Saveri, Eric B. Fastiff, Brendan Glackin, Jordan Elias, Dean M. Harvey; Krause, Kalfayan, Benink & Slavens, San Diego, Ralph B. Kalfayan; Zwerling, Schachter & Zwerling and Dan Drachler for Plaintiffs and Appellants.Mark A. Lemley, Stanford, for 78 Law, Economics, Business and Public Policy Professors as Amici Curiae on behalf or Plaintiffs and Appellants.Edleson & Rezzo, San Diego, Joann F. Rezzo; and Kathryn E. Karcher for Defendants and Respondents.Luce, Forward, Hamilton & Scripps, San Diego, Charles A. Bird, Christopher J. Healey, Todd R. Kinnear; Jones Day, Kevin D. McDonald; Bartlit Beck Herman Palencher & Schott and Peter B. Bensinger, Jr., for Defendant and Respondent Bayer Corporation.

Stinson, Morrison, Hecker, David E. Everson, Heather S. Woodson and Victoria Smith for Defendants and Respondents Hoechst Marion Roussel, Inc., The Rugby Group, Inc., and Watson Pharmaceuticals, Inc.Kirkland and Ellis, Edwin John U, Karen N. Walker, and Gregory Skidmore for Defendant and Respondent Barr Laboratories, Inc.NARES, J.

The plaintiffs in this coordinated class action proceeding sued brand-name drug manufacturer Bayer AG and its subsidiary Bayer Corporation (collectively Bayer); generic drug manufacturers Barr Laboratories, Inc. (Barr), Hoechst Marion Roussel, Inc. (HMR), and HMR's former subsidiary The Rugby Group, Inc. (Rugby) (collectively the generic defendants); and Watson Pharmaceuticals, Inc. (Watson), which purchased Rugby from HMR. Bayer manufactures and markets Cipro, the brand name for ciprofloxacin hydrochloride (ciprofloxacin), an antibiotic prescribed for the treatment of infections. Bayer owned U.S. Patent No. 4,670,444 (the ' 444 patent), which claimed the ciprofloxacin hydrochloride molecule, until the patent expired in December 2003. Plaintiffs asserted causes of action against all defendants for violation of the Cartwright Act (Bus. & Prof.Code, § 16720 et seq.); violation of the Unfair Competition Law (UCL) (Bus. & Prof.Code, § 17200 et seq.); and common law monopolization, arising from an agreement settling litigation between Bayer and Barr concerning the validity of Bayer's '444 patent and related agreements involving the other defendants (collectively, the Cipro agreements or Cipro settlement). Plaintiffs appeal from a judgment entered in favor of defendants after the court granted summary judgment motions filed by Bayer, the generic defendants, and Watson.

Plaintiffs contend (1) the court erred by not ruling that the Cipro agreements are unlawful per se; (2) if the Cipro agreements are not unlawful per se, there is a triable issue of fact as to whether they violate the Cartwright Act under the “rule of reason applied in antitrust cases;” (3) the court followed incorrectly decided federal court decisions in ruling that the Cipro agreements were lawful because they did not restrict competition outside the exclusionary zone of the '444 patent; (4) there is a triable issue of fact under the case law the court followed; (5) the court erred in ruling that it did not have jurisdiction to determine whether Bayer engaged in fraud or inequitable conduct in obtaining the '444 patent because that determination involves substantial questions of patent law; (6) the court erred in granting Watson's motion for summary judgment; and (7) the court erred by not providing any explanation for overruling all of plaintiffs' evidentiary objections.

We hold that a settlement of a lawsuit to enforce a patent does not violate the Cartwright Act if the settlement restrains competition only within the scope of the patent, unless the patent was procured by fraud or the suit for its enforcement was objectively baseless. Because the Cipro agreements undisputedly did not restrain competition beyond the exclusionary scope of the '444 patent, we conclude they do not violate the Cartwright Act. We further conclude that plaintiffs' claim that Bayer's infringement suit against Barr was objectively baseless due to Bayer's inequitable conduct before the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (PTO) in procuring the patent is preempted by federal patent law because plaintiffs' right to relief on that claim necessarily depends on resolution of

a substantial question of federal patent law. Accordingly, we affirm the judgment.

FACTUAL AND PROCEDURAL BACKGROUND

A. The '444 Patent

Bayer's '444 patent covers or “claims” the ciprofloxacin hydrochloride molecule, which is the active ingredient in Cipro. The ' 444 patent expired in December 2003, but the United States Food and Drug Administration (FDA) granted Cipro pediatric exclusivity until June 9, 2004. Consequently, no generic ciprofloxacin product could be lawfully marketed before June 9, 2004, under federal law. (21 U.S.C. § 355a.) B. Hatch–Waxman Act

In 1991 Barr sought FDA approval of a generic version of Cipro under the federal Drug Price Competition and Patent Term Restoration Act of 1984 (the Hatch–Waxman Act) (21 U.S.C. § 355). The Hatch–Waxman Act streamlined the process of obtaining approval of generic versions of branded drugs by allowing a generic manufacturer to file an abbreviated new drug application (ANDA) under 21 United States Code section 355(j). ( Merck KGaA v. Integra Lifesciences I, Ltd. (2005) 545 U.S. 193, 196, fn. 1, 125 S.Ct. 2372, 162 L.Ed.2d 160.) The generic manufacturer does not have to make an independent showing that the generic drug is safe and effective; it need only show that the drug contains the same active ingredients as, and is bioequivalent to, the branded drug. ( Ibid., citing 21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(A)(ii) & (iv); § 355(j)(8)(B).)

Regarding any patents that claim the branded drug, the generic manufacturer's ANDA must certify one of the following: “(I) that such patent information has not been filed, [¶] (II) that such patent has expired, [¶] (III) ... the date on which such patent will expire, or [¶] (IV) that such patent is invalid or will not be infringed by the manufacture, use, or sale of the new drug for which the application is submitted.” (21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(A)(vii).)

A generic manufacturer that files a paragraph IV certification (ANDA IV) must give notice of the certification to any affected patent owners. (21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(B).) The service of the ANDA IV gives an affected patent owner 45 days to file a patent infringement lawsuit against the generic manufacturer. (21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(B)(iii).) If the patent owner files an infringement suit within the 45–day period, FDA approval of the generic manufacturer's ANDA is stayed for 30 months or until a federal district court enters a decision that patent is invalid or not infringed. (21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(2)(B)(iii)(I); In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litigation (E.D.N.Y.2003) 261 F.Supp.2d 188, 193 ( Cipro I ).)

As an incentive for generic manufacturers to file ANDA IV certifications and challenge patents on brand-name drugs, the first ANDA IV filer has the right to exclusively market its generic version of the branded drug for 180 days from the date it begins to commercially market the drug or the date of a final court decision finding the branded drug's patent to be invalid or not infringed. (21 U.S.C. § 355(j)(5)(B)(iv); 21 C.F.R. § 314.07(c)(1) (2009); Cipro I, supra, 261 F.Supp.2d at p. 193.) C. Barr's ANDA and the Ensuing Patent Litigation

In October 1991 Barr filed an ANDA for a generic version of Cipro with an ANDA IV certification asserting that Bayer's '444 patent was invalid or would not be infringed by the manufacture, use or sale of

Barr's generic ciprofloxacin. After receiving notice of Barr's ANDA IV, Bayer filed a patent infringement suit against Barr in the United States District Court for the Southern District of New York. Barr filed affirmative defenses and counterclaims alleging that the '444 patent was invalid and unenforceable due to Bayer's inequitable conduct before the U.S. Patent and Trademark Office (PTO) in procuring the patent.

In March 1996 Barr and Rugby entered into an agreement under which Rugby agreed to finance a portion of the cost of Barr's patent litigation and Barr agreed to provide Rugby half of the profits from its sale of generic ciprofloxacin. In December 1996 Barr, Rugby, and HMR executed an amendment to that agreement providing that HMR succeeded to all of the rights and obligations of Rugby under the agreement. D. The Cipro Agreements

In January 1997, after the district court in the patent litigation had denied cross-motions for partial summary judgment filed by Bayer and Barr and the case had been set for trial, Bayer settled the patent litigation with Barr and other generic drug manufacturers by entering into the Cipro agreements, which consisted of three separate settlement agreements—one with Barr, one with nonparties HMR and Rugby, and one with nonparties Bernard Sherman (Sherman) and Apotex, Inc. (Apotex)—and a “supply agreement” with Barr and HMR.

Under the settlement agreements, Barr, HMR, Rugby, Sherman, and Apotex acknowledged the validity of the '444 patent and related patents held by Bayer. In the settlement agreement between Bayer and Barr, Barr agreed to amend its ANDA to change its ANDA IV certification to an ANDA III certification, precluding Barr from obtaining FDA approval to market generic Cipro until the '444 patent expired. The agreement also provided for an immediate payment of $49.1 million from Bayer to a “Barr Escrow Account.”

Under the supply agreement, Barr and HMR agreed not to manufacture ciprofloxacin or have it manufactured in the United States. The supply agreement gave Bayer the option of either supplying ciprofloxacin that it manufactured to Barr and HMR for distribution in the United States or making quarterly payments to Barr from January 1998 until the '444 patent expired. Bayer chose to make the payments. By December 2003 when Bayer ceased making payments, its payments to Barr totaled approximately $398 million, including the initial payment of $49.1 million. E. Reexamination of and Subsequent Challenges to the '444 Patent

After settling the patent litigation, Bayer filed a request for reexamination of the '444 patent with the PTO. The PTO issued a reexamination certificate confirming the patent's validity, including the validity of claim 12, which covered the ciprofloxacin hydrochloride molecule. (See In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litigation (E.D.N.Y.2005) 363 F.Supp.2d 514, 519 ( Cipro II ).) Subsequently, four generic manufacturers—Ranbaxy Pharmaceuticals, Inc. and Ranbaxy Laboratories Limited (collectively Ranbaxy), Schein Pharmaceutical, Inc., (Schein) Mylan Pharmaceuticals, Inc. and Mylan Laboratories, Inc. (collectively Mylan), and Carlsbad Technology, Inc.—filed ANDAs for ciprofloxacin with ANDA IV certifications and challenged the validity of the reexamined '444 patent in infringement actions that Bayer filed against them.

Ranbaxy withdrew its ANDA IV certification and stipulated with Bayer to the dismissal of the claims and counterclaims

in the patent action between them after entering into a licensing agreement with Bayer. Bayer successfully moved for summary judgment against Schein, Mylan and others on the validity of the '444 patent. ( Bayer AG & Bayer Corp. v. Schein Pharma., (D.N.J.2001) 129 F.Supp.2d 705, affd. (Fed.Cir.2002) 301 F.3d 1306.) After a bench trial, a federal district court upheld the validity of the '444 patent and ruled in favor of Bayer in its infringement action against Carlsbad Technology, Inc. F. Federal Cipro Litigation

In 2000 and 2001, direct and indirect purchasers of Cipro and advocacy groups filed a number of antitrust actions in federal courts challenging the Cipro agreements. The actions were consolidated as “Multidistrict Litigation” (MDL) in the Eastern District of New York. Thereafter, the MDL plaintiffs filed a consolidated complaint against Bayer and the same manufacturers that are generic defendants in the present case, alleging that the Cipro agreements constituted an illegal restraint of trade in violation of the Sherman Act (15 U.S.C. §§ 1–7 et seq.) and various state antitrust and consumer protection laws. ( In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litig. (Fed.Cir.2008) 544 F.3d 1323, 1329 ( Cipro III ).) After the district court denied the MDL plaintiffs' motion for partial summary judgment that the Cipro agreements were illegal per se under the Sherman Act and state antitrust laws, the plaintiffs amended their complaint to add a state law claim that Bayer violated state antitrust law through fraud on the PTO and sham litigation in bringing its patent infringement suit against Barr. ( Cipro III, supra, 544 F.3d at pp. 1329–1330.)

The Cipro III court referred to the MDL plaintiffs' fraud-on-the-PTO claim as a “ Walker Process type” state law claim. The court explained: “In Walker Process Equipment, Inc. v. Food Machinery & Chemical Corp. [ (1965) 382 U.S. 172 [86 S.Ct. 347, 15 L.Ed.2d 247] ( Walker Process ) ], the Supreme Court held that the enforcement of a patent procured by fraud on the patent office may be a violation of the Sherman Act provided that the other elements necessary to a Sherman Act claim are present. [Citation.] Here, however, the plaintiffs alleged a violation of state antitrust laws.” ( Cipro III, supra, 544 F.3d at p. 1330, fn. 6.)

The parties filed cross-motions for summary judgment and the district court denied the plaintiffs' motion and granted the defendants' motion. ( Cipro II, supra, 363 F.Supp.2d 514.) In the district court's view, the “ ultimate question” in the case was “not whether Bayer and Barr had the power to adversely affect competition for ciprofloxacin as a whole, but whether any adverse effects on competition stemming from the [Cipro agreements] were outside the exclusionary zone of the '444 [p]atent.” ( Id. at p. 523.) The court stated that “[u]nless and until the patent is shown to have been procured by fraud, or a suit for its enforcement is shown to be objectively baseless, there is no injury to the market cognizable under existing antitrust law, as long as competition is restrained only within the scope of the patent.” ( Id. at p. 535.) The court noted that because “[a]t least four generic companies filed ANDA IVs after Bayer and Barr entered the [Cipro agreements,] ... it cannot be reasonably argued that the [a]greements created a bottleneck to future generic challenges.” ( Id. at p. 540.)

The Cipro II court concluded that “in the absence of any evidence that the [Cipro agreements] created a bottleneck on challenges to the '444 [p]atent, or that they otherwise restrained competition beyond the scope of the claims of the '444 [p]atent, the [a]greements have not had any anti-competitive effects on the market

for ciprofloxacin beyond that which are permitted under the '444 [p]atent. The fact that Bayer paid what in absolute numbers is a handsome sum to Barr to settle its lawsuit does not necessarily reflect a lack of confidence in the '444 [p]atent, but rather the economic realities of what was at risk. There is simply no precedent for plaintiffs' argument that the parties to a settlement are required to preserve the public's interest in lower prices. Such a rule would only result in parties being less likely to reach settlements, aside from undermining well-settled principles of patent law. Finally, to even attempt to quantify the public's interest in a patent settlement between private parties would require devaluing patents across the board, a result that would contravene the presumption of [patent] validity afforded by Congress and impact the very way patent licenses are handled in countless daily transactions.” ( Cipro II, supra, 363 F.Supp.2d at pp. 540–541.)

The Cipro II court also granted the defendants' motion to dismiss the indirect purchaser plaintiffs' state law Walker Process type claim on the ground it was preempted by federal patent law (28 U.S.C. § 1338(a)) because it depended entirely on a showing of misconduct before the PTO and rested entirely on patent law. ( Cipro II, supra, 363 F.Supp.2d at pp. 542–546.) The court further found that “Bayer's success in its [patent infringement] litigations against Schein, Mylan and Carlsbad forecloses any argument that its lawsuits were shams.” ( Id. at p. 547.) The court rejected the plaintiffs' argument that Bayer's success in those actions was immaterial because the '444 patent had undergone reexamination, stating: “ [R]eexamination does not cure inequitable conduct, and the defense was available to all of the generic challengers.” ( Ibid.)

The plaintiffs timely appealed to the Second Circuit Court of Appeals, which retained jurisdiction over the direct purchaser plaintiffs' appeal but transferred the indirect purchaser and advocacy group plaintiffs' appeal to the federal circuit. ( Ark. Carpenters Health & Welfare Fund v. Bayer AG (2d Cir.2010) 604 F.3d 98, 103 ( Arkansas Carpenters ); Cipro III, supra, 544 F.3d at p. 1327.) The federal circuit affirmed the dismissal of the indirect purchasers' state Walker Process type claims and the “grant of summary judgment ... that the [Cipro agreements] were not in violation of ... the Sherman Act because any anti-competitive effects caused by the [a]greements were within the exclusionary zone of the ['444] patent.” ( Cipro III, supra, 544 F.3d at p. 1341.)

In the direct purchasers' appeal, the Second Circuit likewise affirmed the judgment, noting that most courts considering the issue, including the Second Circuit in In re Tamoxifen Citrate Antitrust Litigation (2nd Cir.2006) 466 F.3d 187 ( Tamoxifen ) “have held that the right to enter into reverse exclusionary payment[ ] agreements fall[s] within the terms of the exclusionary grant conferred by the branded manufacturer's patent.” ( Arkansas Carpenters, supra, 604 F.3d at p. 105.) The Arkansas Carpenters court noted that the Tamoxifen court ruled that a reverse payment agreement settling patent litigation between a branded drug manufacturer and a generic drug manufacturer “did not exceed

The Arkansas Carpenters court explained that the terms “reverse exclusionary payment” and “pay-for-delay” refer to a settlement in which “the patent holder (Bayer) agree[s] to pay the alleged infringer to settle the lawsuit, and in exchange, the alleged infringer agree[s] not to enter the market.” ( Arkansas Carpenters, supra, 604 F.3d at p. 102.) The Tamoxifen court referred to such payments as “reverse payments.” ( Tamoxifen, supra, 466 F.3d at p. 205.)

the scope of the patent where (1) there was no restriction on marketing non-infringing products; (2) a generic version of the branded drug would necessarily infringe the branded firm's patent; and (3) the agreement did not bar other generic manufacturers from challenging the patent.” ( Arkansas Carpenters, supra, 604 F.3d at p. 106, citing Tamoxifen, supra, 466 F.3d at pp. 213–215.) The Arkansas Carpenters court concluded that “as long as Tamoxifen is controlling law, plaintiffs' claims cannot survive.” ( Arkansas Carpenters, supra, 604 F.3d at p. 110.) The court invited the plaintiffs to file a petition for rehearing en banc ( ibid.) and the plaintiffs did so, but the petition was denied. ( Ark. Carpenters Health & Welfare Fund v. Bayer AG (2d Cir.2010) 625 F.3d 779.) G. The Present Action

Plaintiffs' operative pleading in this action is a second amended complaint they filed after this and other state actions were removed to federal court and remanded back to state court in In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litigation (E.D.N.Y.2001) 166 F.Supp.2d 740. As noted, the second amended complaint includes causes of action for violation of the Cartwright Act (Bus. & Prof.Code, § 16720 et seq.); violation of the UCL (Bus. & Prof.Code, § 17200 et seq.); and common law monopolization arising from the Cipro agreements. The trial court granted plaintiffs' motion for class certification and this court upheld a modified certification in In re Cipro Cases I & II (2004) 121 Cal.App.4th 402, 17 Cal.Rptr.3d 1.

The modification was to exclude all Cipro purchasers who paid a flat copayment and would have paid the same copayment for generic ciprofloxacin under the terms of their health coverage. ( In re Cipro Cases I & II, supra, 121 Cal.App.4th at p. 419, 17 Cal.Rptr.3d 1.)

In November 2004 the trial court vacated the trial date and continued the hearing date it had set for defendants' motions for summary judgment pending the federal district court's decision on defense motions for summary judgment filed in the MDL. In March 2005 the district court granted the motions for summary judgment and dismissed the MDL case in the Cipro II decision. The parties in the present action then stipulated to stay the action pending the MDL plaintiffs' appeal of the summary judgment. After the federal circuit issued its decision in Cipro III affirming the summary judgment, the parties stipulated, and the court ordered, that the defendants would file new motions for summary judgment.

The court granted motions for summary judgment filed by Bayer, the generic defendants, and Watson, and entered judgment in favor of defendants. The court ruled that the Cipro agreements did not violate the Cartwright Act because “[t]he undisputed evidence establishes that no triable issue of material fact exists that the agreement did not fall outside the exclusionary scope of the ['444] patent; there is no evidence that the patent suit by Bayer against Barr was objectively baseless; and Plaintiff[s] cannot establish that the settlement was otherwise unlawful.” The court ruled the agreements were not illegal per se and did not violate the Cartwright Act under the “rule of reason” applied in antitrust cases. The court found that as a matter of law, plaintiffs could not establish that the Cipro settlement unreasonably restrained trade because there was no triable issue of fact as to whether it had “anticompetitive effects on competition beyond the exclusionary scope of the ['444] patent itself.” The court stated that “[t]his finding also precludes Plaintiffs'

UCL claim and common law monopoly claim as they are based on the same factual allegations that support the Cartwright Act claim.”

The court ruled that its summary judgment ruling as to Bayer and the generic defendants was dispositive as to Watson's summary judgment motion as well. The court additionally found there was no triable issue of fact as to whether Watson did anything to restrain trade as to ciprofloxacin. The court noted, among other facts, that Watson was not involved in the Cipro agreements and had no relationship to HMR or Rugby when those agreements were made.

DISCUSSION

“ ‘ “Since a summary judgment motion raises only questions of law regarding the construction and effect of the supporting and opposing papers, we independently review them on appeal, applying the same three-step analysis required of the trial court. [Citations.] First, we identify the issues framed by the pleadings since it is these allegations to which the motion must respond by establishing a complete defense or otherwise showing there is no factual basis for relief on any theory reasonably contemplated by the opponent's pleading. [Citations.] [¶] [Second], we determine whether the moving party's showing has established facts which negate the opponent's claim and justify a judgment in [the] movant's favor.... [¶] When a summary judgment motion prima facie justifies a judgment, the third and final step is to determine whether the opposition demonstrates the existence of a triable, material factual issue.” ’ ” ( Pepperell v. Scottsdale Ins. Co. (1998) 62 Cal.App.4th 1045, 1054, 73 Cal.Rptr.2d 164.)

I. Legality of the Cipro Agreements

Plaintiffs first contend the court erred by not ruling that the Cipro agreements are illegal per se under the Cartwright Act. The Cartwright Act (Bus. & Prof.Code, § 16700 et seq.) “prohibits every trust, defined as ‘a combination of capital, skill or acts by two or more persons' for specified anticompetitive purposes. (§ 16720.) Section 16720 generally codifies the common law prohibition against restraint of trade. [Citation.] [ ] [¶] The federal Sherman Act prohibits every ‘contract, combination ... or conspiracy, in restraint of trade.’ ( 15 U.S.C. § 1.) ‘The similar language of the two acts reflects their common objective to protect and promote competition. [Citations.] Since the Cartwright Act and the federal Sherman Act share similar language and objectives, California courts often look to federal precedents under the Sherman Act for guidance.’ ” ( Fisherman's Wharf Bay Cruise Corp. v. Superior Court (2003) 114 Cal.App.4th 309, 334, 7 Cal.Rptr.3d 628.)

All further statutory references are to the Business & Professions Code unless otherwise noted.

Section 16720, subdivision (a) specifies as a trust purpose a combination “[t]o create or carry out restrictions in trade or commerce.” Subdivisions (b) through (e) of section 16720 specify various anticompetitive schemes and agreements constituting trusts, and section 16726 states that, except as otherwise specified in the Cartwright Act, “every trust is unlawful, against public policy and void.”

Courts have limited the reach of the Cartwright Act to restraints of trade that are unreasonable. ( UAS Management, Inc. v. Mater Misericordiae Hospital (2008) 169 Cal.App.4th 357, 364, 87 Cal.Rptr.3d 81.) “Generally, in determining whether conduct unreasonably restrains trade, ‘[a] rule of reason analysis requires a determination of whether ... its anti-competitive effects outweigh its

pro-competitive effects.’ ” ( Bert G. Gianelli Distrib. Co. v. Beck & Co. (1985) 172 Cal.App.3d 1020, 1048, 219 Cal.Rptr. 203, disapproved on other grounds in Dore v. Arnold Worldwide, Inc. (2006) 39 Cal.4th 384, 389–390, 394, fn. 2, 46 Cal.Rptr.3d 668, 139 P.3d 56.) However, “ ‘[c]ertain restraints [of trade] which lack redeeming virtue are conclusively presumed to be unreasonable’ ” and therefore deemed illegal per se. ( UAS Management, Inc. v. Mater Misericordiae Hospital, supra, 169 Cal.App.4th at p. 364, 87 Cal.Rptr.3d 81; Morrison v. Viacom, Inc. (1998) 66 Cal.App.4th 534, 540, 78 Cal.Rptr.2d 133.)

Plaintiffs contend the Cipro agreements are illegal per se, and the trial court would have found them so if it had not followed Tamoxifen and other federal cases supporting the proposition that a reverse-payment settlement between a patent holder and alleged infringer in Hatch–Waxman litigation is legal as long as the settlement does not restrain competition beyond the exclusionary scope of the patent, and there is no showing that the patent was procured by fraud or that the suit for its infringement was objectively baseless. Plaintiffs contend these cases were wrongly decided. We disagree.

In Tamoxifen, branded drug manufacturer and patent holder Zeneca, Inc., and related entities (collectively Zeneca) and generic drug manufacturer Barr entered into a reverse exclusionary payment settlement after a federal district court rendered a judgment declaring Zeneca's patent for the drug tamoxifen invalid, and while Zeneca's appeal of that judgment was pending. ( Tamoxifen, supra, 466 F.3d at pp. 193–194.) The plaintiffs in Tamoxifen alleged the settlement violated antitrust laws. ( Id. at pp. 196–197.) Considering the sufficiency of plaintiffs' complaint, the Tamoxifen court declined to conclude, and noted that the plaintiffs did not ask it to conclude, “that reverse payments are per se violations of the Sherman Act such that an allegation of an agreement to make reverse payments suffices to assert an antitrust violation.” ( Id. at p. 206, original italics.) The Tamoxifen court adopted the holding in Cipro II that “ ‘[u]nless and until the patent is shown to have been procured by fraud, or a suit for its enforcement is shown to be objectively baseless, there is no injury to the market cognizable under existing antitrust law, as long as competition is restrained only within the scope of the patent.’ ” ( Tamoxifen, supra, 466 F.3d at p. 213, quoting Cipro II, supra, 363 F.Supp.2d at p. 535.) Affirming the district court's judgment dismissing the complaint and denying plaintiffs leave to amend, the Tamoxifen court concluded that “in the absence of any plausible allegation that Zeneca's patent infringement lawsuit was baseless or that the Settlement Agreement otherwise restrained competition beyond the scope of the tamoxifen patent, [the plaintiffs'] complaint would fail to state a claim on which relief can be granted.” ( Tamoxifen, supra, 466 F.3d at p. 221.)

Before Tamoxifen was decided, the district court in Cipro I, addressing the Cipro settlement challenged here, noted that “ per se analysis is reserved for a small number of cases involving agreements in restraint of trade that experience teaches have no redeeming value and a pernicious anticompetitive effect. This case involves the rights of a patent holder whose patent has been scrutinized on reexamination by the PTO and repeatedly challenged in court, but has never been found invalid. This case also involves the Hatch–Waxman Amendments—a new statutory scheme creating a novel, low-cost method for challenging the validity of drug patents. Lastly, this case involves settlement agreements, the type of agreements, generally speaking, encouraged by the legal system

and entered into with great frequency. These circumstances pose significant obstacles to per se treatment of the challenged agreements.” ( Cipro I, supra, 261 F.Supp.2d at p. 233.)

The Cipro I court stated that “when patents are involved, case law directs that the exclusionary effect of the patent must be considered before making any determination as to whether the alleged restraint is per se illegal. Therefore, the proper analysis in this case is whether the plaintiffs have proven as a matter of law that the challenged agreements restrict competition beyond the exclusionary effects of the 444 Patent.” ( Cipro I, supra, 261 F.Supp.2d at p. 249.) The court observed that because the '444 patent covered the active ingredient in all Cipro products, until the patent “either is invalidated or expires, it lawfully precludes the manufacture and use of any generic product containing the compound ciprofloxacin hydrochloride regardless of the form or method of delivery. Therefore, the restrictions in the Supply Agreement on manufacturing Cipro appear within the confines of Bayer's lawful patent monopoly.” ( Id. at p. 250.) The court concluded that the Cipro agreements, including the supply agreement, “do not restrict competition in areas other than those protected by Bayer's 444 Patent and, thus, are not per se illegal under the Sherman Act.” ( Ibid.)

Noting that the policies underlying patent law and the Sherman Act conflict to some extent, the Cipro I court reasoned that “[t]he flexibility necessary to balance these competing policies, particularly in the context of a new statutory scheme, suggests that a rule of reason rather than a per se analysis should be employed in this case.” ( Cipro I, supra, 261 F.Supp.2d at p. 255.) The court noted incentives created by the Hatch–Waxman Act “have led to generic investment in product development, patent review and product challenges through litigation.... To maximize these incentives, a generic company should be permitted to choose not only when to commence patent litigation, but also when to terminate it. Otherwise, the incentives to mount an ANDA IV challenge could be reduced.” ( Id. at p. 256.)

The Cipro I court also recognized that the public policy favoring the settlement of disputes was an important factor in its analysis, stating: “[T]he American legal process encourages the settlement of lawsuits where possible, and unless the law explicitly states otherwise, neither party is obligated to litigate to a final conclusion. Nothing in the legislative history supports a conclusion that Hatch–Waxman lawsuits cannot be settled. Moreover, a rule that makes it per se illegal to settle a Hatch–Waxman lawsuit, like the Bayer/Barr patent litigation, limits the options available to both generic and brand-name manufacturers. If brand-name manufacturers are unable to control or limit their risk by settling Hatch–Waxman litigation, they, like generic manufacturers, may be less inclined to invest the research and development (‘R & D’) costs associated with bringing new drugs to the market. The pharmaceutical industry depends greatly on R & D and the economic returns to intellectual property created when a successful new drug is brought to market.... A rule prohibiting settlements of Hatch–Waxman patent litigation can have grave consequences for R & D and, in turn, severe consequences for consumers.” ( Cipro I, supra, 261 F.Supp.2d at p. 256.) “Although a policy in favor of settlement of litigation cannot save a per se violation from the [strictures] of the Sherman Act, a rule that too quickly condemns actions as per se illegal, potentially chilling efforts to research and develop new drugs and challenge the patents on brand-name

drugs, does competition—and thus, the Sherman Act—a disservice.” ( Ibid.)

In another decision predating Tamoxifen, the Eleventh Circuit Court of Appeals, considering a reverse payment settlement of a Hatch–Waxman infringement suit that the district court had found to be illegal per se, stated: “If this case merely involved one firm making monthly payments to potential competitors in return for their exiting or refraining from entering the market, we would readily affirm the district court's order [granting summary judgment]. This is not such a case, however, because one of the parties owned a patent.” ( Valley Drug Co. v. Geneva Pharms., Inc. (11th Cir.2003) 344 F.3d 1294, 1304 ( Valley Drug ).) The Valley Drug court noted that “[a] patent grants its owner the lawful right to exclude others” ( ibid.) and that “a patentee can choose to exclude everyone from producing the patented article or can choose to be the sole supplier itself.” ( Id. at p. 1305.) “Unlike some kinds of agreements that are per se illegal whether engaged in by patentees or anyone else, such as tying or price-fixing, the exclusion of infringing competition is the essence of the patent grant.... ‘[W]hen patents are involved ... the exclusionary effect of the patent must be considered before making any determination as to whether the alleged restraint is per se illegal.’ ” ( Id. at p. 1306, quoting Cipro I, supra, 261 F.Supp.2d at p. 249.)

The Valley Drug court noted that the only time the United States Supreme Court “has addressed the circumstances under which the patent immunity from antitrust liability can be pierced, it held that the antitrust claimant must prove that the patentee enforced a patent with the knowledge that the patent was procured by fraud on the Patent Office.” ( Valley Drug, supra, 344 F.3d at p. 1307, citing Walker Process, supra, 382 U.S. at p. 177, 86 S.Ct. 347.) “Good faith procurement furnishes a complete defense to the antitrust claim. [Citation.] Justice Harlan's concurrence [in Walker Process ] explained that the effect of antitrust liability on the incentives for innovation and disclosure created by the patent regime must be taken into account when a court considers whether a patentee is stripped of its immunity from the antitrust laws: [¶] ‘It is well also to recognize the rationale underlying this decision, aimed of course at achieving a suitable accommodation in this area between the differing policies of the patent and antitrust laws. To hold, as we do, that private suits may be instituted under § 4 of the Clayton Act to recover damages for Sherman Act monopolization knowingly practiced under the guise of a patent procured by deliberate fraud, cannot well be thought to impinge upon the policy of the patent laws to encourage inventions and their disclosure. Hence, as to this class of improper patent monopolies, antitrust remedies should be allowed room for full play. On the other hand, to hold, as we do not, that private antitrust suits might also reach monopolies practiced under patents that for one reason or another may turn out to be voidable under one or more of the numerous technicalities attending the issuance of a patent, might well chill the disclosure of inventions through the obtaining of a patent because of fear of the vexations or punitive consequences of treble-damage suits. Hence, this private antitrust remedy should not be deemed to reach § 2 monopolies carried on under a nonfraudulently procured patent.’ ” ( Valley Drug, supra, 344 F.3d at p. 1307, quoting Walker Process, supra, 382 U.S. at pp. 179–180, 86 S.Ct. 347, conc. opn. of Harlan, J.)

Further addressing the need to balance the conflicting polices behind patent law and antitrust law, the Valley Drug court noted that although patent and antitrust

laws necessarily clash, “ ‘the two regimes seek the same object: the welfare of the public ... Antitrust law forbids certain agreements tending to restrict output and elevate prices and profits above the competitive level. Patent law also serves the interests of consumers by protecting invention against prompt imitation in order to encourage more innovation than would otherwise occur.’ ” ( Valley Drug, supra, 344 F.3d at pp. 1307–1308.) The Valley Drug court concluded that the fact the district court found the patent at issue in that case to be invalid alone was “insufficient to render the patent's potential exclusionary effects irrelevant to the antitrust analysis.” ( Id. at p. 1309.)

The plaintiffs in Valley Drug argued that patent rights do not include the right to pay infringers—an argument the Valley Drug court viewed as implying “that any exclusion resulting from payment rather than judicial enforcement is not protected from per se antitrust liability by the patent laws.” ( Valley Drug, supra, 344 F.3d at p. 1309.) The court rejected that argument based on the important role settlement plays in the enforcement of patent rights, stating: “Appellees have not explained why a monetary payment as part of a patent litigation settlement should be flatly prohibited as a per se violation, particularly where the alleged infringer has not yet caused the patentee any harm and the patentee does not have a damages claim to bargain with. [Citations.] [¶] We cannot conclude that the exclusionary effects of the Agreements not to enter the market were necessarily greater than the exclusionary effects of the '207 patent merely because Abbott paid Geneva and Zenith in return for their respective agreements. If Abbott had a lawful right to exclude competitors, it is not obvious that competition was limited more than that lawful degree by paying potential competitors for their exit. The failure to produce the competing terazosin drug, rather than the payment of money, is the exclusionary effect, and litigation is a much more costly mechanism to achieve exclusion, both to the parties and to the public, than is settlement. [Citation.] To hold that an ostensibly reasonable settlement of patent litigation gives rise to per se antitrust liability if it involves any payment by the patentee would obviously chill such settlements, thereby increasing the cost of patent enforcement and decreasing the value of patent protection generally. We are not persuaded that such a per se rule would be an appropriate accommodation of the competing policies of the patent and antitrust laws.” ( Ibid.)

Although the Valley Drug court stated that the size of a reverse or “exit” payment may raise suspicion that the settling parties lacked faith in the validity of the patent in question, the court also noted that “[g]iven the asymmetries of risk and large profits at stake, even a patentee confident in the validity of its patent may pay a potential infringer a substantial sum in settlement.” ( Valley Drug, supra, 344 F.3d at p. 1310.) As an example, the court noted the $398 million that Bayer paid Barr in the Cipro settlement even “though the ['444] patent was subsequently approved by the PTO on reexamination and unsuccessfully challenged in court three times.” ( Ibid., citing Cipro I, supra, 261 F.Supp.2d at p. 234.)

The Valley Drug court, in remanding the case to the district court, concluded that neither per se analysis nor the rule of reason was an appropriate approach for determining whether the settlement at issue violated antitrust law, stating: “Rule of reason and per se analysis are both aimed at assessing the anticompetitive effects of particular conduct; what is required here is an analysis of the extent to which antitrust liability might undermine the encouragement of innovation and disclosure,

or the extent to which the patent laws prevent antitrust liability for such exclusionary effects.” ( Valley Drug, supra, 344 F.3d at p. 1311, fn. 27.)

In Schering–Plough Corp. v. FTC (11th Cir.2005) 402 F.3d 1056 ( Schering ), the Eleventh Circuit Court of Appeals vacated a decision by the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) finding that Hatch–Waxman settlements between branded drug manufacturer Schering–Plough Corporation (Schering) and generic manufacturers Upsher–Smith Laboratories, Inc. (Upsher) and ESI Lederle, Inc. (ESI) violated the FTC Act and the Sherman Act. ( Id. at p. 1062.) Schering manufactured and marketed an extended release potassium chloride product called K–Dur 20, and owned a formulation patent on the extended-release coating that surrounds the potassium chloride on the product. ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at p. 1058.) Upsher filed an ANDA IV seeking FDA approval of a generic version of K–Dur 20 and Schering filed a patent infringement suit against Upsher. ( Id. at pp. 1058–1059.) Schering and Upsher entered into a settlement of the infringement suit that included Schering's agreeing to an early entry date for Upsher's generic version of K–Dur, and Upsher's granting Schering licenses to market five other Upsher products, including a time-release niacin product used to reduce cholesterol. ( Id. at p. 1059.) The settlement involved a “three-part license deal, which called for Schering to pay [Upsher] (1) $60 million in initial royalty fees; (2) $10 million in milestone royalty payments; and (3) 10% or 15% royalties on sales.” ( Id. at p. 1060.)

ESI also sought FDA approval for a generic version of K–Dur 20 and was sued by Schering for patent infringement. ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at p. 1060.) Schering and ESI entered into a settlement agreement under which Schering allowed ESI to market its competing generic three years before Schering's patent expired ( ibid.) and “agreed to pay ESI a $5 million noncontingent payment, representing legal fees, and an additional $10 million contingent on ESI's FDA approval. Schering and ESI also entered into a contemporaneous license agreement whereby ESI granted Schering the licenses to [two ESI drugs] in exchange for $15 million.” ( Id. at p. 1061, fn. 8.)

The FTC filed an administrative complaint challenging the legality of the settlements under the FTC Act and the Sherman Act, and the complaint was tried before an administrative law judge (ALJ) who rejected the FTC's theories that the settlement agreements at issue were anticompetitive. ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at p. 1061.) Noting that the FTC's theories required either a presumption that Schering's patent in question was invalid or that Upsher's and ESI's generic products did not infringe it, the ALJ ruled that the presumptions had no basis in law or fact. ( Ibid.) The ALJ found that the fact the settlements included payments did not make them anticompetitive per se. “Rather, the strength of the patent itself and its exclusionary power needed to be assessed. The [ALJ's] decision highlighted the FTC's failure to prove that, absent a payment, either better settlement agreements or litigation results would have effected an earlier entry date for the generics. Finally, the ALJ found no proof that Schering maintained an illegal monopoly within the relevant ... market.” ( Id. at pp. 1061–1062.)

On appeal of the ALJ's decision to the full Commission, the Commission reversed the ALJ, ruling the settlements included agreements to defer generic entry dates that injured competition and consumers. ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at p. 1062.) Regarding the settlement payments, “the

Commission determined that neither the $60 million to Upsher nor the $30 million to ESI represented legitimate consideration for the licenses granted by Upsher or ESI's ability to secure FDA approval of its generic. Consequently, the Commission prohibited settlements under which the generic receives anything of value and agrees to defer its own research, development, production or sales activities.” ( Id. at p. 1062, fn. omitted.)

The Schering court noted that both the ALJ and Commission applied the rule of reason in analyzing the Schering settlements, albeit under two different methodologies. ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at p. 1064.) Following Valley Drug, the court stated: “We think that neither the rule of reason nor the per se analysis is appropriate in this context. We are bound by our decision in Valley Drug where we held both approaches to be ill-suited for an antitrust analysis of patent cases because they seek to determine whether the challenged conduct had an anticompetitive effect on the market. [Citation.] By their nature, patents create an environment of exclusion, and consequently, cripple competition. The anticompetitive effect is already present. ‘What is required here is an analysis of the extent to which antitrust liability might undermine the encouragement of innovation and disclosure, or the extent to which the patent laws prevent antitrust liability for such exclusionary effects.’ [Citation.] Therefore, in line with Valley Drug, we think the proper analysis of antitrust liability requires and examination of: (1) the scope of the exclusionary potential of the patent; (2) the extent to which the agreements exceed that scope; and (3) the resulting anticompetitive effects.” ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at pp. 1065–1066, fn. omitted.)

The Schering court noted that “[a]lthough the exclusionary power of a patent may seem incongruous with the goals of antitrust law, a delicate balance must be drawn between the two regulatory schemes. Indeed, application of antitrust law to markets affected by the exclusionary statutes set forth in patent law cannot discount the rights of the patent holder. [Citation.] Therefore, a patent holder does not incur antitrust liability when it chooses to exclude others from producing its patented work.” ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at p. 1067.) “What patent law does not do, however, is extend the patentee's monopoly beyond its statutory right to exclude.” ( Ibid.)

The Schering court also addressed the policy favoring settlement, stating: “The general policy of the law is to favor the settlement of litigation, and the policy extends to the settlement of patent infringement suits. [Citations.] Patent owners should not be in a worse position, by virtue of the patent right, to negotiate and settle surrounding lawsuits. We find the terms of the settlement to be within the patent's exclusionary power, and ‘reflect a reasonable implementation’ of the protections afforded by patent law.” ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at p. 1072.)

In considering whether the settlements at issue had anticompetitive effects—i.e., were an “ ‘unfair method of competition’ ” ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at p. 1072)—the Schering court elaborated on the policy favoring settlement of litigation and the detriment that would result from a rule prohibiting reverse payment settlements in patent litigation. The court reiterated that “[t]he efficiency-enhancing objectives of a patent settlement are clear, and ‘[p]ublic policy strongly favors settlement of disputes without litigation.’ ” ( Id. at pp. 1072–1073.) The court stated that “[t]he Commission's inflexible compromise-without-payment theory neglects to understand that ‘[r]everse payments are a natural by

product of the Hatch–Waxman process.’[ ] [Citation.] ... A prohibition on reverse-payment settlements would ‘reduce the incentive to challenge patents by reducing the challenger's settlement options should he be sued for infringement, and so might well be thought anticompetitive.’ [Citation.] [¶] There is no question that settlements provide a number of private and social benefits as opposed to the inveterate and costly effects of litigation. [Citation.] Patent litigation breeds a litany of direct and indirect costs, ranging from attorney and expert fees to the expenses associated with discovery compliance. Other costs accrue for a variety of reasons, be it the result of uncompromising legal positions, differing strategic objectives, heightened emotions, lawyer incompetence, or sheer moxie. [Citations.] [¶] Finally, the caustic environment of patent litigation may actually decrease product innovation by amplifying the period of uncertainty around the drug manufacturer's ability to research, develop, and market the patented product or allegedly infringing product.” ( Id. at pp. 1074–1075.)

The Tamoxifen court explained that “reverse payments are particularly to be expected in the drug-patent context because the Hatch–Waxman Act created an environment that encourages them.” ( Tamoxifen, supra, 466 F.3d at p. 206.) The court noted that “under the Hatch–Waxman Act, the patent holder ordinarily brings suit shortly after the paragraph IV ANDA has been filed—before the filer has spent substantial sums on the manufacturing, marketing, or distribution of the potentially infringing generic drug. The prospective generic manufacturer therefore has relatively little to lose in litigation precipitated by a paragraph IV certification beyond litigation costs and the opportunity for future profits from selling the generic drug ... [¶] Accordingly, a generic marketer has few disincentives to file an ANDA with a paragraph IV certification. The incentive [to file and ANDA IV], by contrast, may be immense: the profits it will likely garner in competing with the patent holder without having invested substantially in the development of the drug, and, in addition, possible entitlement to a 180–day period (to be triggered at its inclination) during which it would be the exclusive seller of the generic drug in the market.” ( Id. at pp. 206–207, fn. omitted.) On the other hand, “[t]he patent holder's risk if it loses the resulting patent suit is correspondingly large: It will be stripped of its patent monopoly. At the same time, it stands to gain little from winning other than the continued protection of its lawful monopoly over the manufacture and sale of the drug in question. [¶] ‘Hatch–Waxman essentially redistributes the relative risk assessments and explains the flow of settlement funds and their magnitude. Because of the Hatch–Waxman scheme, [the generic challengers] gain[ ] considerable leverage in patent litigation: the exposure to liability amount[s] to litigation costs, but pale[s] in comparison to the immense volume of generic sales and profits.’ ” ( Ibid.)

The Schering court found that the settlement agreements at issue “fell well within the protections of the [subject] patent, and were therefore not illegal.” ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at p. 1076.) The court concluded: “Simply because a brand-name pharmaceutical company holding a patent paid its generic competitor money cannot be the sole basis for a violation of antitrust law. This alone underscores the need to evaluate the strength of the patent. Our conclusion, to a degree, and we hope that the FTC is mindful of this, reflects policy. Given the costs of lawsuits to the parties, the public problems associated with overcrowded court dockets, and the correlative public and private benefits of settlements, we fear and reject a rule of law that would automatically invalidate any agreement where a patent-holding pharmaceutical manufacturer settles an infringement case by negotiating the generic's entry date, and, in an ancillary transaction, pays for other products licensed by the generic. Such a result does not represent the confluence of patent and antitrust law.” ( Ibid.)

In the same month that Schering was decided, the district court in Cipro II granted defendant's motions for summary judgment and dismissal. As noted above, the Cipro II judgment was affirmed in Cipro III as to the direct purchaser plaintiffs and Arkansas Carpenters as to the indirect purchaser and advocacy group plaintiffs. The Cipro III court stated: “[I]n cases such as this, wherein all anticompetitive effects of the settlement agreement are within the exclusionary power of the patent, the outcome is the same whether the court begins its analysis under antitrust law by applying a rule of reason approach to evaluate the anti-competitive effects, or under patent law by analyzing the right to exclude afforded by the patent. The essence of the inquiry is whether the agreements restrict competition beyond the exclusionary zone of the patent. This analysis has been adopted by the Second and the Eleventh Circuits and by the district court below and we find it to be completely consistent with Supreme Court precedent.” ( Cipro III, supra, 544 F.3d at p. 1336, citing Walker Process, supra, 382 U.S. at pp. 175–177, 86 S.Ct. 347 [although the Sherman Act may be violated when a patent is procured by fraud, a patent is an exception to the general rule against monopolies].)

The Cipro III court concluded: “Pursuant to statute, a patent is presumed to be valid, , and patent law bestows the patent holder with ‘the right to exclude others from profiting by the patented invention.’ [Citation.] A settlement is not unlawful if it serves to protect that to which the patent holder is legally entitled—a monopoly over the manufacture and distribution of the patented invention. [Citation.] Thus, the district court correctly concluded that there is no legal basis for restricting the right of a patentee to choose its preferred means of enforcement and no support for the notion that the Hatch–Waxman Act was intended to thwart settlements. [Citation.] ... [I]f ‘there is nothing suspicious about the circumstances of a patent settlement, then to prevent a cloud from being cast over the settlement process a third party should not be permitted to haul the parties to the settlement over the hot coals of antitrust litigation.’ ” ( Cipro III, supra, 544 F.3d at p. 1337, quoting Asahi Glass Co. v. Pentech Pharms., Inc. (N.D.Ill.2003) 289 F.Supp.2d 986, 992.) Accordingly, the Cipro III court found “the analysis by the district court to be fully supported in law and to demonstrate that it was cognizant of the legal standards applied by the regional circuits and governmental agencies in addressing agreements involving exclusion payments in the context of the Hatch–Waxman Act.” ( Cipro III, supra, 544 F.3d at p. 1337.)

The Arkansas Carpenters court likewise affirmed the Cipro II judgment based on the holding in Tamoxifen and other courts that “the right to enter into reverse exclusionary payment agreements fall[s] within the terms of the exclusionary grant conferred by the branded manufacturer's patent.” ( Arkansas Carpenters, supra, 604 F.3d at p. 105.) The Arkansas Carpenters court followed the Tamoxifen court's analysis that a reverse payment agreement settling patent litigation between a branded drug manufacturer and a generic drug manufacturer does “not exceed the scope of the patent where (1) there [is] no restriction on marketing non-infringing products; (2) a generic version of the branded drug would necessarily infringe the branded firm's patent; and (3) the agreement [does] not bar other generic manufacturers from challenging the patent.” ( Arkansas Carpenters, supra, 604 F.3d at p. 106, citing Tamoxifen, supra, 466 F.3d at pp. 213–215.)

We agree with the reasoning of these cases and conclude that it applies equally to antitrust claims under the Cartwright Act. Under the Cartwright Act, as under the Sherman Act, the “illegal per se” designation is reserved for agreements or practices that have a pernicious effect on competition and lack any redeeming virtue. ( Corwin v. Los Angeles Newspaper Service Bureau, Inc. (1971) 4 Cal.3d 842, 853, 94 Cal.Rptr. 785, 484 P.2d 953; Morrison v. Viacom, Inc. (1998) 66 Cal.App.4th 534, 540, 78 Cal.Rptr.2d 133; MacManus v. A.E. Realty Partners (1983) 146 Cal.App.3d 275, 285, 194 Cal.Rptr. 567.) Considering the important public policies underlying patent law ( Valley Drug, supra, 344 F.3d at pp. 1307–1308) and favoring the settlement of patent litigation ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at pp. 1074–1075) and the fact that the Cipro agreements did not restrain competition outside the exclusionary zone of the '444 patent, we cannot view the Cipro agreements as lacking any redeeming virtue. Accordingly, we conclude they are not unlawful per se.

We further conclude that the Cipro agreements do not violate the Cartwright Act under rule-of-reason analysis or the analysis the Eleventh Circuit Court of Appeals held to be applicable to settlements of Hatch–Waxman litigation in Valley Drug and Schering, which requires “examination of: (1) the scope of the exclusionary potential of the patent; (2) the extent to which the agreements exceed that scope; and (3) the resulting anticompetitive effects.” ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at pp. 1065–1066, fn. omitted.) We find the reasoning of the federal cases discussed above regarding the legality of settlements of Hatch–Waxman patent litigation to be sound and applicable to plaintiffs' cause of action under the Cartwright Act. We agree with the Cipro III court that because a patent is presumed to be valid and gives the patent holder the right to exclude others from marketing the patented invention, a settlement of patent infringement litigation “is not unlawful if it serves to protect that to which the patent holder is legally entitled—a monopoly over the manufacture and distribution of the patented invention.” ( Cipro III, supra, 544 F.3d at p. 1337.) Therefore, in accordance with Cipro II and Tamoxifen, we conclude that unless a patent was procured by fraud, or a suit for its enforcement was objectively baseless, a settlement of the enforcement suit does not violate the Cartwright Act if the settlement restrains competition only within the scope of the patent. ( Tamoxifen, supra, 466 F.3d at p. 213; Cipro II, supra, 363 F.Supp.2d at p. 535.)

The principle that an agreement is not unlawful under California and federal antitrust law if it restrains competition only within the exclusionary scope of a patent is reflected in Fruit Machinery Co. v. F.M. Ball & Co. (1953) 118 Cal.App.2d 748, 258 P.2d 852 ( Fruit Machinery ). In Fruit Machinery, the plaintiff licensee of a patent holder successfully sued the defendant for breach of a contractual obligation to pay plaintiff royalties for use of a patented machine, and the defendant claimed it was absolved of that obligation because, among other reasons, the plaintiff had created a monopoly in violation of state and federal antitrust law. ( Fruit Machinery, supra, 118 Cal.App.2d at pp. 750, 760, 258 P.2d 852.) In rejecting that claim, the Fruit Machinery court noted that the licensing arrangement in question was not “beyond the scope of the patent rights and within the proscription of the antitrust laws....” ( Id. at p. 762, 258 P.2d 852.) The court noted it would not “be legally improper or incompetent for the patentee, his exclusive licensee, and the latter's sublicensees, by agreements such as these parties have made, to give themselves a commercial

advantage over others in industry. The very purpose of the patent law is to encourage inventive effort by according the inventor and his assigns control over the invention and protection in the exercise of the rights accorded him as patentee. Defendant has not shown that the parties, in executing and carrying out the sublicense agreement in suit, exercised rights or powers not accorded them by the patent law or abused any rights or powers accorded them by that law.” ( Ibid., italics added.) The Fruit Machinery court found various antitrust law decisions cited by the defendant to be inapplicable, noting that “[t]he greater number of them dealt with situations in which no patent rights were involved. In those in which the exercise of patent rights [was] involved, it appeared that the patentee or his assignee went beyond that which was necessary or incidental to the scope of his patent and brought himself within the proscription of the antitrust laws.” ( Fruit Machinery, supra, 118 Cal.App.2d at pp. 762–763, 258 P.2d 852.)

Plaintiffs and amici curiae focus on the reverse exclusionary payment or pay-for-delay aspect of the Cipro settlement in arguing that the settlement violates antitrust law. Plaintiffs argue that Hatch–Waxman litigation can and should be settled without reverse payments. However, we agree with the Valley Drug court's view that deeming an ostensibly reasonable settlement of patent litigation illegal per se under antitrust law if the settlement “involves any payment by the patentee would obviously chill such settlements, thereby increasing the cost of patent enforcement and decreasing the value of patent protection generally.” ( Valley Drug, supra, 344 F.3d at p. 1309.) As the Schering court noted, “the size of the payment, or the mere presence of a payment, should not dictate the availability of a settlement remedy. Due to the ‘asymmetrics of risk and large profits at stake, even a patentee confident in the validity of its patent may pay a potential infringer a substantial sum in settlement.’ ” ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at p. 1075, quoting Valley Drug, supra, 344 F.3d at p. 1310.)

A group of professors filed an amici curiae brief entitled: “Brief Amici Curiae of 78 Intellectual Property Law, Antitrust Law, Economics, and Business Professors in Support of Appellant.”

We agree with the Schering court's observation that reverse payment settlements are a natural byproduct of patent litigation under the Hatch–Waxman Act and that a rule prohibiting them could harm competition by reducing the incentive to challenge patents by reducing the challenger's settlement options in a suit for infringement. ( Schering, supra, 402 F.3d at pp. 1074–1075.) Emphasizing the private and social benefits that the settlement of patent litigation provides, the Schering court appropriately concluded that “[s]imply because a brand-name pharmaceutical company holding a patent paid its generic competitor money cannot be the sole basis for a violation of antitrust law.” ( Id. at p. 1076.)

Plaintiffs and amici curiae point to In re Cardizem CD Antitrust Litig. (6th Cir.2003) 332 F.3d 896 ( Cardizem ) as showing a conflict in the federal circuits regarding the legality of reverse payment settlements of Hatch–Waxman patent litigation. In that case the district court found that a reverse-payment settlement between branded drug manufacturer HMR and generic manufacturer Andrx Pharmaceuticals, Inc., was illegal per se and the Cardizem court affirmed. However, the Cardizem court noted that in condemning the HMR/Andrx agreement, the district court “ ‘emphasized that the

agreement ... restrained Andrx from marketing other bioequivalent or generic versions of Cardizem that were not at issue in the pending litigation.... Thus, the court found that the agreement's restrictions extended to noninfringing and/or potentially noninfringing versions of generic Cardizem.’ ” ( Id. at p. 909, fn. 13, quoting Cipro I, supra, 261 F.Supp.2d at p. 242.)

In other words, the reverse payment settlement in Cardizem restrained competition beyond the exclusionary zone of the subject patent. As the Cipro III court noted, “although the Sixth Circuit found a per se violation of the antitrust laws in In re Cardizem, the facts of that case are distinguishable from this case and from the other circuit court decisions. In particular, the settlement in that case included, in addition to a reverse payment, an agreement by the generic manufacturer to not relinquish its 180–day exclusivity period, thereby delaying the entry of other generic manufacturers. [Citation.] Furthermore, the agreement provided that the generic manufacturer would not market non-infringing versions of the generic drug. [Citation.] Thus, the agreement clearly had anticompetitive effects outside the exclusion zone of the patent.” ( Cipro III, supra, 544 F.3d at p. 1335, italics added.) We further note that unlike the Valley Drug, Schering and Tamoxifen courts, and the trial and appellate courts in the federal Cipro litigation, the Cardizem court did not consider, much less attempt to balance, the competing policies underlying antitrust law and patent law or address the policy favoring settlement of litigation.

The Cipro III court added: “To the extent that the Sixth Circuit may have found a per se antitrust violation based solely on the reverse payments, we respectfully disagree.” ( Cipro III, supra, 544 F.3d at p. 1335.)

Contrary to amici curiae's assertion that “[t]he Second Circuit rule endorsed by the trial court is far outside the mainstream of judicial ... analysis of exclusionary settlements,” every reported decision to date addressing the legality of a reverse-payment settlement of Hatch–Waxman litigation that does not restrain competition beyond the exclusionary scope of the patent has concluded that the settlement does not violate antitrust law. We conclude that because the Cipro agreements undisputedly did not restrain competition beyond the exclusionary scope of the '444 patent, they do not violate the Cartwright Act.

We acknowledge that amici curiae, the FTC, and the Department of Justice have advocated various approaches under which reverse-payment settlements of patent infringement litigation under the Hatch–Waxman Act could be deemed to violate antitrust law even when they do not restrain competition beyond the exclusionary scope of a patent. However, considering the necessity of maintaining a proper balance between the competing policies underlying patent law and antitrust law, we believe that any rule prohibiting such settlements of Hatch–Waxman litigation should be made by Congress rather than the courts.

II. Sham Litigation Claim

Plaintiffs contend that even if the Cipro settlement does not violate California law unless the '444 patent is shown to have been procured by fraud or a suit for its enforcement is shown to be objectively baseless, the court erred in granting summary judgment because there is as triable issue of fact as to whether Bayer's patent infringement action against Barr was an objectively baseless or “sham” lawsuit. “To prove sham litigation, a plaintiff must show (1) ‘the lawsuit [to] be objectively baseless in the sense that no reasonable litigant could realistically expect success on the merits,’ and (2) that the litigant's ‘subjective motivation’ for bringing the action

was a sham seeking to conceal a knowing attempt to interfere with a competitor.” ( Cipro II, supra, 363 F.Supp.2d at p. 547, citing Professional Real Estate Investors, Inc. v. Columbia Pictures Industries, Inc. (1993) 508 U.S. 49, 60–61, 113 S.Ct. 1920, 123 L.Ed.2d 611.) Plaintiffs' position on appeal appears to be that they could show Bayer's patent infringement suit was objectively baseless based on evidence of Bayer's inequitable conduct in procuring the '444 patent—an issue they contend was not litigated in Bayer's suits against generic manufacturers for infringement of the '444 patent following the Cipro settlement.

Bayer argues, and the trial court ruled, that plaintiffs' sham litigation claim was not a proper basis for opposing defendants' summary judgment motions because it was not pleaded in plaintiffs' second amended complaint. The trial court further ruled that “[e]ven if such allegations were included in the [second amended complaint], there is no evidence or legal support the suit was objectively baseless or was a sham.” The trial court quoted the Cipro II court's finding that “Bayer's success in its [patent infringement] litigations against Schein, Mylan and Carlsbad forecloses any argument that its lawsuits were shams.” ( Cipro II, supra, 363 F.Supp.2d at p. 547.)

Regarding plaintiffs' inequitable conduct claim, the trial court ruled: “Plaintiffs cannot meet the objectively baseless standard by resorting to allegations of inequitable conduct since the [second amended complaint] does not allege inequitable conduct, much less that Bayer's infringement suit against Barr was objectively baseless or a sham. Even if there were such allegations, inequitable conduct is only an equitable defense to a patent infringement suit which, if proven, can render the entire patent unenforceable. [Citation.] As such, Bayer's alleged inequitable conduct in procuring the patent is not relevant to the case at hand as it pertains to [p]laintiffs' antitrust claims.” The trial court also decided that the “determination of ... inequitable conduct would involve substantial questions of patent law, which this Court does not have jurisdiction to decide.”

It is difficult to fault the trial court's ruling that “[p]laintiffs failed to allege that Bayer's infringement suit was objectively baseless, [or] was sham litigation ... and [p]laintiffs cannot defeat the motion for summary judgment by doing so now.” It is well settled that “the pleadings set the boundaries of the issues to be resolved at summary judgment. [Citations.] A ‘plaintiff cannot bring up new, unpleaded issues in his or her opposing papers. [Citation.]’ [Citations.] A summary judgment or summary adjudication motion that is otherwise sufficient ‘cannot be successfully resisted by counterdeclarations which create immaterial factual conflicts outside the scope of the pleadings; counterdeclarations are no substitute for amended pleadings.’ Thus, a plaintiff wishing ‘to rely upon unpleaded theories to defeat summary judgment’ must move to amend the complaint before the hearing.” ( Oakland Raiders v. National Football League (2005) 131 Cal.App.4th 621, 648, 32 Cal.Rptr.3d 266.)

It is a stretch to interpret the second amended complaint as raising the issue of whether Bayer's patent infringement suit against Barr was objectively baseless due to inequitable conduct or for any other reason. The allegations of the second amended complaint reflect plaintiffs' theory that the Cipro agreements injure competition in violation of the Cartwright Act regardless of the validity of Bayer's '444 patent or the merits of its infringement suit against Barr, and merely suggest that the '444 patent might have been ruled

invalid but for the Cipro settlement. The second amended complaint alleges that the patent holder and ANDA IV filer “must be adversaries” and that “the former presumes the patent is valid, enforceable and infringed, while the latter must assert that the patent is invalid, unenforceable and/or not infringed.” Thus, plaintiffs' allegations that Barr asserted the patent was invalid or unenforceable do not constitute an allegation by plaintiffs that Bayer's infringement suit was baseless; they merely reflect that Barr assumed the adversarial role it was required to assume in filing an ANDA IV. The closest the second amended complaint comes to expressly alleging that Bayer's infringement suit lacked merit is the allegation that “[b]ut for the Cipro Agreements and other agreements between Bayer and Barr: ... the finder-of-fact in the patent litigation could have found that the 444 patent was invalid, unenforceable or not infringed. (Italics & underscoring added.) This allegation, which essentially avers that Bayer might have lost its infringement suit had it been litigated to completion, is not reasonably construed as an allegation that the suit was objectively baseless or a sham.

Plaintiffs also suggest that Bayer's infringement suit would not have been successful by alleging that “[b]ut for the Cipro Agreements, generic ciprofloxacin would have been on the United States market by January 1997.”

In any event, assuming the complaint sufficiently pleads the claim that Bayer's patent infringement suit was objectively baseless due to inequitable conduct, we agree with the trial court and the Cipro II court that “Bayer's success in its [patent infringement] litigations against Schein, Mylan and Carlsbad forecloses any argument that its lawsuits were shams.” ( Cipro II, supra, 363 F.Supp.2d at p. 547.) As the Cipro II court noted: “ ‘A winning lawsuit is by definition a reasonable effort at petitioning for redress and therefore is not a sham.’ ” ( Ibid., quoting Professional Real Estate Investors, Inc. v. Columbia Pictures Industries, Inc., supra, 508 U.S. at p. 61, fn. 5, 113 S.Ct. 1920.)

The Cipro II court was addressing Bayer's motion “for summary judgment that Bayer's suits against Barr an the subsequent '444 Patent challengers were not sham litigation as a matter of law.” ( Cipro II, supra, 363 F.Supp.2d at p. 547.)

Plaintiffs assert that none of the challenges to the '444 patent by generic manufacturers following the Cipro settlement and the patent's reexamination involved the issue of Bayer's inequitable conduct. However, as the Cipro II court noted, “reexamination does not cure inequitable conduct, and the defense was available to all of the generic challengers.” ( Cipro II, supra, 363 F.Supp.2d at p. 547.) It seems highly unlikely that a generic manufacturer motivated to challenge the '444 patent would overlook or forgo a meritorious defense to Bayer's infringement suit that would render the suit objectively baseless.

The Cipro II court addressed this point, stating: “At oral argument, plaintiffs asserted that the court should give little weight to these subsequent failed attacks because none of them raised what plaintiffs believe to be the most forceful attack on the '444 Patent-namely, inequitable conduct. Plaintiffs argue that this defense required extensive discovery and would take a long period of time to prepare and try, and that this explains why none of the subsequent challengers raised this issue. [¶] But this argument is not very convincing in light of the fact that one of the challenges—Carlsbad's, on the ground of obviousness—also required extensive discovery and resulted in a nine-day bench trial. It is difficult to accept the notion that Carlsbad abandoned a stronger argument because it would have presumably required a greater effort, especially since Barr had already done most of the preparatory work on the inequitable conduct issue.” ( Cipro II, supra, 363 F.Supp.2d at p. 530.)

Further, even if there is evidence creating a triable issue of fact as to whether Bayer's patent infringement suit was objectively baseless due to Bayer's inequitable conduct in procuring the '444 patent, we conclude that plaintiffs' sham-litigation claim is preempted by federal patent law. “The district courts [of the United States] shall have original jurisdiction of any civil action arising under any Act of Congress relating to patents.... Such jurisdiction shall be exclusive of the courts of the states in patent ... cases.” (28 U.S.C. § 1338(a).) Federal jurisdiction over cases arising under patent law “ ‘extend[s] only to those cases in which a well-pleaded complaint establishes either that federal patent law creates the cause of action or that the plaintiff's right to relief necessarily depends on resolution of a substantial question of federal patent law, in that patent law is a necessary element of one of the well-pleaded claims.’ ” ( Holiday Matinee, Inc. v. Rambus, Inc. (2004) 118 Cal.App.4th 1413, 1422, 13 Cal.Rptr.3d 766, quoting Christianson v. Colt Industries Operating Corp. (1988) 486 U.S. 800, 808–809, 108 S.Ct. 2166, 100 L.Ed.2d 811, italics added.)

Plaintiffs' right to relief under the Cartwright Act and UCL, under their sham litigation theory, depends on the resolution of whether Bayer engaged in inequitable conduct in the procurement of its '444 patent that rendered its infringement suit against Barr objectively baseless. When a state law claim involves a patent holder's conduct in obtaining its patent, the claim is preempted by federal patent law unless the plaintiff pleads and proves that the patent holder engaged in fraud before the PTO. ( Hunter Douglas, Inc. v. Harmonic Design, Inc. (Fed.Cir.1998) 153 F.3d 1318, 1336–1337, overruled on other grounds in Midwest Industries, Inc. v. Karavan Trailers, Inc. (Fed.Cir.1999) 175 F.3d 1356, 1358–1359; see also Nobelpharma AB v. Implant Innovations, Inc. (Fed.Cir.1998) 141 F.3d 1059, 1068 [“[W]hether conduct in procuring or enforcing a patent is sufficient to strip a patentee of its immunity from the antitrust laws is to be decided as a question of Federal Circuit law.” (Fn. omitted.) ].) More specifically, a determination of whether alleged inequitable conduct in the procurement of a patent constitutes unfair competition is within the exclusive jurisdiction of the Federal Circuit Court of Appeals. ( Lockwood v. Sheppard, Mullin, Richter & Hampton (2009) 173 Cal.App.4th 675, 686, 93 Cal.Rptr.3d 220, citing Pro–Mold & Tool Co. v. Great Lakes Plastics (Fed.Cir.1996) 75 F.3d 1568, 1574.) Thus, plaintiffs' claim that Bayer's infringement suit against Barr was objectively baseless due to inequitable conduct is preempted by federal patent law because it necessarily depends on resolution of a substantial question of federal patent law—i.e., whether Bayer engaged in inequitable conduct in the procurement of its patent.

Plaintiffs emphasize on appeal that they are not asserting a claim of fraud on the PTO.

Plaintiffs argue they are not seeking to hold Bayer liable for its conduct in procuring or enforcing the '444 patent, but rather are challenging the “collusive payment” that ended the patent suit. However, it is immaterial to the federal jurisdiction issue that plaintiffs' claims do not directly seek to hold Bayer liable for inequitable conduct in procuring the '444 patent; plaintiffs' antitrust and unfair competition claims are preempted by federal patent law because a necessary element of those claims is that Bayer's infringement suit against Barr was objectively baseless due to Bayer's inequitable

conduct in the procurement of the patent and, accordingly, the '444 patent was invalid. In their reply brief, plaintiffs similarly contend their claims “are not premised on Bayer's conduct before the [PTO]; they are premised on Bayer's conduct in settling its own patent case with a payment not to compete.” (Original boldface.) However, because the payment in question did not restrain competition beyond the exclusionary scope of the '444 patent, it does not subject defendants to antitrust liability unless plaintiffs can prove their claim that the Bayer's infringement suit was objectively baseless, which claim is premised on Bayer's conduct before the patent office.

Plaintiffs argue that state courts have jurisdiction to determine patent law issues such as patent validity when such determination is ancillary and necessary to the main action, citing, among other authority, Mattel, Inc. v. Luce, Forward, Hamilton & Scripps (2002) 99 Cal.App.4th 1179, 1186, 121 Cal.Rptr.2d 794. The Mattel court concluded that a state claim against the law firm for malicious prosecution was not preempted by federal copyright law even though the defendant asserted that the underlying trademark infringement action could have been brought only in federal court. The court relied in part on cases holding that “ ‘if the suit is to enforce or to revoke a patent licensing or other similar agreement, it “is not a suit under the patent laws of the United States, and cannot be maintained in a federal court as such.” [Citations.] It follows ... that in an action in a state court based upon such an agreement, the state court can, where it becomes necessary for it to do so in order to decide the case before it, pass upon the meaning, the scope, the validity, or the infringement of the patent.’ ” ( Id. at p. 1187, 121 Cal.Rptr.2d 794.) However, the present action is not a contract action seeking to enforce or revoke a patent licensing agreement; it arises from a settlement of patent litigation, and plaintiffs' sham litigation claim requires adjudication of the validity of the patent in the context of the determination of whether Bayer's patent infringement suit against Barr was objectively baseless.

Plaintiffs also rely on ClearPlay, Inc. v. Abecassis (Fed.Cir.2010) 602 F.3d 1364, which involved state law claims by ClearPlay, Inc. (ClearPlay), a manufacturer of DVD players against patent holder Nissim Corp. (Nissim) arising from a patent licensing agreement that the parties entered into in settlement of a patent infringement suit that Nissim brought against ClearPlay. Nissim claimed that ClearPlay breached the license agreement and filed a motion to enforce the parties' settlement. While that motion was pending, Nissim informed retailers selling ClearPlay's products that the products were not licensed and the retailer's continuing to sell them could constitute patent infringement. ( Id. at pp. 1364–1365.) ClearPlay responded by bringing a state law action against Nissim that included claims for tortious interference with contractual relationships, tortious interference with potentially advantageous business relationships, breach of the license agreement by interfering with ClearPlay's business operations, breach of the covenant of good faith and fair dealing, and violation of Florida's Deceptive and Unfair Trade Practices Act. ( Id. at pp. 1365, 1367–1368.) The ClearPlay court decided that although “questions of patent infringement are addressed at various points in the communications that are at issue in ClearPlay's complaint, and while it is possible that patent law issues could arise in the course of litigating any one of ClearPlay's claims, it is equally clear that none of those claims necessarily turns on an issue of patent law. That is, in the case of each

asserted claim, there is at least one theory of relief that would not require the resolution of a patent law issue.” ( Id. at p. 1368.) ClearPlay is inapposite. Because the Cipro settlement did not restrain competition beyond the exclusionary scope of the '444 patent, plaintiffs' claims here, unlike state law claims in ClearPlay, necessarily turn on the patent law issue of whether Bayer's infringement suit was objectively baseless due to inequitable conduct.

Plaintiffs argue it is error to revisit the federal jurisdiction issue decided by the district court in In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litigation, supra, 166 F.Supp.2d 740, when it remanded this action to state court. However, as this court explained in Moreau v. San Diego Transit Corp. (1989) 210 Cal.App.3d 614, 258 Cal.Rptr. 647 ( Moreau ): “In making its jurisdictional determination on a motion for remand, the [federal] district court looks no further than the complaint and the motion for removal. This limitation is one aspect of the ‘well-pled complaint’ rule which holds a plaintiff is the ‘master’ of his complaint and he may craft his causes of action, if he so desires, to exclude federal jurisdiction. Under the rule a federal question must appear from the complaint and not from any preemption defense which might be raised in state court and which might ultimately defeat the cause of action. [Citation.] [¶] However, an independent corollary to the ‘well-pled complaint’ rule is the ‘artful pleading’ rule or the ‘doctrine of complete preemption.’ This doctrine states that while couched in state contract or tort terms, federal jurisdiction exists if the issues actually raise an essentially federal question.... [¶] When a federal court grants a motion for remand in the present context, it does nothing more than determine the complaint fails, either directly or by operation of the ‘artful pleading’ doctrine, to state a question arising under federal law. It does not determine whether a preemption defense can be successfully offered in state court when the entire case is considered.” ( Id. at pp. 620–621, 258 Cal.Rptr. 647, italics added; accord, Ruiz v. Sysco Food Services (2004) 122 Cal.App.4th 520, 531–532, 18 Cal.Rptr.3d 700 [“[T]he trial court was not required or allowed to accord any collateral estoppel effect to the federal district court's remand order, which was not a final judgment but rather a procedural order concerning the appropriate forum.”]; McCormick v. Travelers Ins. Co. (2001) 86 Cal.App.4th 404, 103 Cal.Rptr.2d 258 [after removal of state tort claims to federal court and federal court's subsequent remand to state court, state court properly granted defendant's motion for judgment on the pleadings on the ground of federal preemption]; AT & T Communications, Inc. v. Superior Court (1994) 21 Cal.App.4th 1673, 1680, 26 Cal.Rptr.2d 802 [doctrine of law of the case applies only to appellate court decisions and a remand ruling is a jurisdictional ruling, not a final judgment on the merits of a preemption defense]; United Airlines, Inc. v. Superior Court (1991) 234 Cal.App.3d 1085, 1090, 286 Cal.Rptr. 159 [“The exercise of a federal district court's unreviewable power to remand claims to state court ... is not necessarily the same as a determination of whether those claims on their merits—even though not removable to federal court—would nonetheless be preempted by federal law if asserted by way of defense in state court.”]; Coker v. Purdue Pharma Co. (Tenn.Ct.App., Nov. 30, 2006, No. W2005–02525–COA–R3–CV) 2006 WL 3438082, 2006 Tenn.App. LEXIS 757

[after federal court remanded case to state court on the ground the complaint's allegations of misrepresentation to the PTO in the procurement of a patent could be proven without resorting to question of federal law, state trial court properly determined federal preemption was a valid defense to the misrepresentation claims and granted judgment on the pleadings].)

Although it is not essential to our preemption analysis, we note that the theory of liability alleged in plaintiffs' second amended complaint that caused the federal district court to remand this case to state court in In re Ciprofloxacin Hydrochloride Antitrust Litigation, supra, 166 F.Supp.2d 740 lacks merit, as the district court later acknowledged. The court remanded the case based on its conclusion “that plaintiffs have asserted at least one theory by which they may establish state antitrust violations without resorting to a determination of patent law. Plaintiffs' complaints allege there would have been generic competition in the market for ciprofloxacin prior to the expiration of Bayer's patent if Bayer had not reached an unreasonably anti-competitive agreement with Barr, HMR, and Rugby.... [Plaintiffs] asserted that, as a matter of fact, Bayer would have authorized Barr to distribute ciprofloxacin by granting Barr a license, or by other means, had Barr not agreed to drop its challenge to the validity of the '444 patent in exchange for large cash payments.” ( Id. at p. 748.)
This theory of liability fails because any restraint on competition resulting from Bayer's decision to enter into the Cipro agreements instead of some other licensing agreement was within the exclusionary zone of the ' 444 patent and thus is not a basis for imposing antitrust or unfair competition liability on defendants. As the Cipro II court explained: “[P]laintiffs' assertion that Bayer's payment to Barr is anti-competitive because, without it, Bayer and Barr would have agreed on an earlier entry date for Barr or would have otherwise fashioned a more pro-competitive agreement must also fail. This assertion ignores the fact that, if defendants were within their rights (more specifically, the patent right) in reaching the settlement they did, consumers have no right to second-guess whether some different agreement would have been more palatable.” ( Cipro II, supra, 363 F.Supp.2d at p. 536.) Regarding its basis for remanding the case, the district court stated that “[u]pon further reflection, I have concluded that patent law imposes no such restriction against cash payments by a patent holder, and, accordingly, antitrust law does not impose such a restriction.” ( Id. at p. 536, fn. 21.) In other words, Bayer was not restricted by patent or antitrust law to settlement options more favorable to competition than the settlement it reached.

Plaintiffs' contention that there is a triable issue of fact as to whether Bayer's infringement suit against Barr was objectively baseless due to inequitable conduct in procuring the '444 patent is not a basis to reverse the judgment. To the extent a sham-litigation claim is sufficiently pleaded in plaintiffs' second amended complaint, it arises from and is preempted by federal patent law.

We do not hold that the issue of whether a patent infringement suit is objectively baseless can never be decided by a state court; there may be cases where a suit can be shown to be objectively baseless without the necessity of resolving a substantial question of federal patent law.

III. Unfair Competition and Common Law Monopoly Claims

Our conclusion that defendants are not liable under the Cartwright Act for entering into the Cipro agreements is also dispositive of plaintiffs' causes of action for violation of the UCL and common law monopolization. “The purpose of federal and state antitrust laws is to protect and promote competition for the benefit of consumers. [Citations.] Antitrust laws are designed to prohibit only unreasonable restraints of trade, meaning conduct that unreasonably impairs competition and harms consumers. [Citations.] If the same conduct is alleged to be both an antitrust violation and an ‘unfair’ business act or practice for the same reason—because it unreasonably restrains competition and harms consumers—the determination that the conduct is not an unreasonable restraint of trade necessarily implies that the conduct is not

‘unfair’ toward consumers. To permit a separate inquiry into essentially the same question under the unfair competition law would only invite conflict and uncertainty and could lead to the enjoining of procompetitive conduct.” ( Chavez v. Whirlpool Corp. (2001) 93 Cal.App.4th 363, 375, 113 Cal.Rptr.2d 175; accord, Drum v. San Fernando Valley Bar Assn. (2010) 182 Cal.App.4th 247, 254, 106 Cal.Rptr.3d 46 [conduct that is deemed reasonable and condoned under antitrust law does not violate the UCL].)

Regarding plaintiffs' cause of action for common law monopolization, it is questionable whether such a cause of action exists under California law. The federal district court in In re Intel Corp. Microprocessor Antitrust Litigation (D.Del.2007) 496 F.Supp.2d 404 dismissed a common law monopolization claim on the ground that “the common law tort of monopolization is not cognizable under California law....” ( Id. at p. 420; accord, Lorenzo v. Qualcomm, Inc. (S.D.Cal.2009) 603 F.Supp.2d 1291; Luxpro Corp. v. Apple, Inc. (W.D.Ark.2009) 658 F.Supp.2d 921, 933.) To the extent such a cause of action is cognizable under California law, it fails for the same reason plaintiffs' UCL cause of action fails—i.e., because it is based on the same conduct alleged to be a violation of the Cartwright Act. Conduct that has been determined not to unreasonably restrain competition under statutory antitrust law cannot logically be deemed to unreasonably restrain competition under a common law monopolization theory.

The trial court properly granted summary judgment on plaintiffs' causes of action for violation of the UCL and common law monopolization as well as their cause of action for violation of the Cartwright Act. The court also properly ruled that its summary judgment ruling as to Bayer and the generic defendants was also dispositive as to Watson's summary judgment motion, since plaintiffs sought to hold Watson liable solely as a conspirator for the allegedly unlawful conduct of the other defendants.

IV. Evidentiary Objections

Plaintiffs contend the court erred by not providing any explanation for overruling all of their evidentiary objections, relying on Nazir v. United Airlines, Inc. (2009) 178 Cal.App.4th 243, 254–257, 100 Cal.Rptr.3d 296 ( Nazir ) in which the Court of Appeal held that the trial court abused its discretion by issuing a blanket ruling sustaining all but one of defendants' 764 evidentiary objections in a summary judgment proceeding.

Here, the court did not sustain the evidentiary objections in question; it overruled them. In Reid v. Google, Inc. (2010) 50 Cal.4th 512, 534, 113 Cal.Rptr.3d 327, 235 P.3d 988, the California Supreme Court held that when a trial court ruling on a summary judgment motion “fails to rule expressly on specific evidentiary objections, it is presumed that the objections have been overruled, the trial court considered the evidence in ruling on the merits of a summary judgment motion, and the objections are preserved on appeal.” Thus, the trial court's blanket ruling overruling plaintiffs' evidentiary objections left plaintiffs in no worse a position than they would have been in if the court had failed to issue any ruling at all on the objections. The objections were preserved on appeal and plaintiffs were free to challenge the trial court's consideration of specific items of objected-to evidence on appeal. Because plaintiffs have not argued that the admission of any specific evidence constituted prejudicial error, the court's ruling on plaintiffs' evidentiary objections provides

no basis to disturb the judgment.

We note that plaintiffs complain that the court improperly considered evidence concerning the litigation challenging the '444 patent that occurred after the Cipro settlement and the reexamination of the patent. We do not find the admission of this evidence to be prejudicial, however, because the essential facts of those suits were established as undisputed by plaintiffs' responses to Bayer's separate statement of undisputed facts in support of its motion for summary judgment, Nos. 29–33.

DISPOSITION

The judgment is affirmed.

WE CONCUR: BENKE, Acting P.J., and AARON, J.

FN* McGaughey v. Bayer Corporation (Super. Ct. San Diego County, No. GIC752290); Relles v. Bayer Corporation (Super. Ct. L.A. County, No. BC239083); Samole v. Bayer AG (Super. Ct. S.F. City and County, No. 316349); Garber v. Bayer AG (Super. Ct. S.F. City and County, No. 316518); Lee v. Bayer AG (Super. Ct. S.F. City and County, No. 316670); Patane v. Bayer AG (Super. Ct. S.F. City and County, No. 318457); Moore v. Bayer Corporation (Super. Ct. Sonoma County, No. SCZ228356); Moore v. Bayer Corporation (Super. Ct. Sonoma County, No. 228384); Senior Action Network v. Bayer AG (Super. Ct. S.F. City and County, No. 400750).


Summaries of

In re Cipro Cases I & Ii.[nine Coordinated Cases *]

Court of Appeal, Fourth District, Division 1, California.
Oct 31, 2011
200 Cal.App.4th 442 (Cal. Ct. App. 2011)
Case details for

In re Cipro Cases I & Ii.[nine Coordinated Cases *]

Case Details

Full title:In re CIPRO CASES I & II.[Nine coordinated cases *]

Court:Court of Appeal, Fourth District, Division 1, California.

Date published: Oct 31, 2011

Citations

200 Cal.App.4th 442 (Cal. Ct. App. 2011)
134 Cal. Rptr. 3d 165
11 Cal. Daily Op. Serv. 13504

Citing Cases

Ruins-Ca v. eBay, Inc.

"'"Since the Cartwright Act and the federal Sherman Act share similar language and objectives, California…